Economics

Monetary Policy

  • Monetary Policy
    Bullard Has Fed History on His Side in Rate-Hike Debate with Yellen
    St. Louis Fed President James Bullard has moved decisively and vocally from the dove to hawk camp over the past year, and is now predicting a rate hike in the first quarter of next year – in contrast to Fed Chair Janet Yellen, who still does not appear to see one coming before the middle of the year.  The economy, Bullard said, was “way ahead of schedule for labor-market improvement.” But it’s not just the unemployment picture that’s changed dramatically over the past half-year; the inflation picture has as well. Today’s Geo-Graphic updates one we did in March, comparing the level of unemployment and inflation today with the levels they were at at the start of previous rate-hiking cycles going back to 1994.  In March, unemployment was at the top of this range, but inflation was well below where it was in ’94, ’97, ’99, and ’04.  The picture is very different today, with the Fed’s preferred measure of inflation, PCE, having risen to 1.6% from 1% back in February.  All other major measures are also well up.  Moreover, three of these measures are now above where they were when the Fed started tightening in ’99.  The Fed funds rate, however, is way below where it was at the beginning of previous rate-tightening cycles.  This suggests that Bullard is right to be asking whether the Fed is at risk of “get[ting] behind the curve” if it doesn’t adjust its tightening timetable. Federal Reserve: Economic Projections of Fed Board Members and Fed Bank Presidents FiveThirtyEight: Inflation Isn’t Rising Yet, But The Fed is Watching Closely Economist: A Tight Spot for America's Recovery Financial Times: US Recovery Rouses Inflation Concerns   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Sub-Saharan Africa
    Is the IMF Going to Save Ghana’s Troubled Economy?
    This is a guest post by Cheryl Strauss Einhorn, a journalist and adjunct professor at the Columbia University Graduate School of Journalism Long hailed as evidence of Africa’s growing political and economic stability, Ghana is suffering a reversal of fortune. One week ago as President John Mahama arrived in Washington for the U.S.-Africa Summit, his government finally admitted it needed urgent help to fix its faltering economy and contacted the International Monetary Fund for financial assistance. "The ultimate objective is to stabilize the cedi (Ghanaian currency) in order that domestic prices will be brought under control," Finance Minister Seth Terkper told a local radio station Joy FM. Indeed, despite being rich in natural resources with plentiful oil, gold, and cocoa, West Africa’s second largest economy has been in disarray, its problems laying bare many of the challenges facing the continent as a whole. Ghana’s oil production levels remain stagnant and gold prices are languishing, yet the government has drastically increased its spending. Critics charge that it has overspent on pricey offices and golf courses, as well as public sector wages and subsidies for utilities and fuel. The result: investors have lost faith in Ghana’s ability to pay its debts. Ghana’s cedi is the worst performing currency in the world this year. Its value has been nearly cut in half against the U.S. dollar, sparking a significant rise in the cost of living. Inflation, at 15 percent, is at a four year high and economic growth is slowing just as the nation faces a double digit budget deficit as a percent of GDP. The economic crisis has led to a series of labor protests. News reports recount five separate demonstrations organized against Ghana’s government in July alone with the largest gathering thousands in the streets of all ten regional capitals. More protests are reportedly planned. Yet an IMF bailout may not provide any immediate relief. Instead, it is likely to inflict marginal pain on Ghanaians as the IMF demands faster spending curbs that will impact public wages, subsidies, and taxes. Moreover, Finance Minister Terkper told reporters that Ghana will continue to extend its borrowings, despite expensive terms. Bond yields are near 10 percent. Yet he said Ghana plans to seek over one billion dollars from international investors to fund new infrastructure projects and pay down debts. Terkper predicts an IMF package would increase the bond offer’s appeal, signaling that the IMF believes Ghana will improve its macroeconomic management. But is that assumption correct? President Mahama has been a poor economic steward and stubbornly refused to go to the IMF amid claims that Ghana could fix its own problems, which it did not, or could not. And Ghana has been here before, having tapped the IMF multiple times. Ghana had a golden opportunity in 2005, when as part of a global relief plan for poor nations, most of its debt was cleared. Yet today its economy is in shambles. The question remains: Is Ghana a stable and favorable investment destination, or is it a cyclical economy, beholden to a few volatile commodity markets with a government unable, or unwilling to exercise fiscal and economic restraint?
  • China
    Is the BRICS Contingent Reserve Arrangement a Substitute for the IMF?
    Russian President Vladimir Putin has hailed the new BRICS contingent reserve arrangement (CRA) as a substitute for the IMF, saying that it “creates the foundation for an effective protection of our national economies from a crisis in financial markets." But does it? Under the terms of the arrangement, China can, without being on an IMF program, borrow up to $6.2 billion; Brazil, Russia, and India $5.4 billion; and South Africa $3 billion.  But this is chicken feed compared to Russia and Brazil’s crisis-borrowing from the IMF over the past twenty years, as we show in the top figure above.  The IMF approved lending to Russia of $38 billion (SDR 24.786 billion) in the 1990s.  In 2002 alone, the IMF approved a 15-month stand-by credit arrangement of about $30 billion for Brazil.  Net private financial flows to emerging markets today are roughly 10 times what they were in 2002, meaning that the size of the loans necessary to address balance of payments financing problems would be even larger now. The BRICS countries know this, which is why they maintain such vast pools of foreign exchange reserves, as we show in the bottom figure. The notion that $5.4 billion from the BRICS CRA would make a difference to Russia in a genuine financial crisis is ridiculous.  Putin’s statement is clearly political hyperbole, which is why Russia currently holds over $400 billion in reserves. Time: The BRICS Don’t Like the Dollar-Dominated World Economy, but They’re Stuck With It Financial Times: The BRICS Bank Is a Glimpse of the Future People's Bank of China: Treaty for the Establishment of a BRICS Contingent Reserve Arrangement IMF: The IMF and Russia in the 1990s   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • China
    Is the BRICS Bank More "Democratic" Than the World Bank?
    The launch of the new BRICS development bank “reflects the disparity and democratic deficiency in the global governance and is trying to restart, to rethink that,” according to Nobel economist Joseph Stiglitz.  But is the BRICS bank really more “democratic” than the World Bank, whose governance legitimacy its founders are challenging? As the Geo-Graphic above shows, the voting share of the World Bank’s founding members has fallen over the years from 100% to 49.7%.  This means that its 37 founders currently have less voting power than the five BRICS bank founders will ever have within their new institution.  That’s because the BRICS bank articles of agreement do not allow the founders’ voting share to fall below 55% - ever, no matter what the bank’s future membership looks like. This is like saying that immigrants can have the vote, but only until they become 45% of the population – then they cap out. Where’s the democracy in that? Geo-Graphics: Hurling BRICS at the World Bank and the $ RT: How the West Created BRICS New Development Bank Wall Street Journal: Five Things to Know About the New BRICS Bank International Bank for Reconstruction and Development: Subscriptions and Voting Power of Member Countries   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • China
    Hurling BRICS at the World Bank and the $
    Brazil, Russia, India, China, and South Africa (the “BRICS”) made a splash last week with the official launch of their new development bank.  The backers made no secret of their intention to challenge the way things are done in the established international financial and monetary architecture. The irony is that India and China are the biggest beneficiaries of the current development bank architecture. They are the World Bank’s largest borrowers.  And Brazil is number 9.  As shown in the graphic above, these three nations have $66bn in World Bank loans outstanding, 32% more than the new BRICS bank’s entire initial subscribed capital of $50bn.  So it would appear that for the foreseeable future the World Bank will remain a considerably more important source of development financing for the BRICS than their own development bank. At the bank’s launch, Russian president Vladimir Putin took a shot at the prevailing global monetary architecture, contrasting it with the BRICS’ vision.  “The international monetary system … depends a lot on the U.S. dollar, or, to be precise, on the monetary and financial policy of the U.S. authorities. The BRICS countries want to change this.” However, the entire paid-in capital stock of the new BRICS bank will be in U.S. dollars.  Just 10 percent of the World Bank’s paid-in capital was contributed in U.S. dollars; the rest was contributed in member countries’ national currencies. So whose currency regime is more dependent on the dollar? Sixth BRICS Summit: Fortaleza Declaration Macro and Markets: BRICS and Mortals The Economist: An Acronym with Capital International Bank for Reconstruction and Development: Information Statement   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Monetary Policy
    Yellen vs. Bullard on Wages and Inflation: Who Is Right?
    Wage growth is “not a threat to inflation,” Fed Chair Janet Yellen said on June 18.  “[With] our 2 percent inflation objective, we could see wages growing at a more rapid rate” before having to worry. “When unemployment goes into the five range, that is going to below the natural rate,” St. Louis Fed President James Bullard said on July 9.  “I think we are going to overshoot here on inflation.” Who is right? In today’s Geo-Graphic, we look at the relationship between wage growth and inflation over the last twenty years.  Perhaps surprisingly, we find virtually none (an R-Squared of 0.03).  Wage growth has routinely exceeded so-called core inflation (consumer goods inflation excluding energy and food) by large amounts without the latter picking up.  One explanation for this phenomenon may be the growth of imports as a percentage of GDP, from 9% in 1994 to 16% today, which acts to keep tradeables prices down.  This supports Yellen’s position. This does not mean, however, that wage growth should not concern the Fed.  On the contrary, as we can see from the figure on the left, unusually high wage growth—above 4%—preceded the last two recessions, in 2001 and 2007.  The explanation may lie in the fact that high wage growth induces people to assume more debt that they would otherwise. Rapid wage growth was associated with rising debt service burdens during both periods, as shown in the figure on the right.  Increasing debt service payments tend to crowd out other forms of consumer spending, and make households more vulnerable if expected wage increases fail to materialize. Annualized wage growth at present is still moderate, running at about 2.3%.  But it is clearly on the rise.  The household debt service ratio, however, is at its lowest level since the series began in 1980, and household debt is less than it was in Q1 2008—though it has started moving up again. In short, the monetary history of the past twenty years suggests that wage growth at current or moderately higher levels is unlikely to cause a significant rise in consumer price inflation.  Yet a continued trending up in wage growth would likely presage a rise in household leverage, which is a credible indicator of economic instability ahead.  But at the current low leverage levels, far ahead. The Economist: Waiting for Inflation Wall Street Journal: America Inc. Wakes Up to Wage Inflation VoxEU: The Impact of Low-Income Economies on U.S. Inflation Financial Times: Fed Bond Buying Set to End in October   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • China
    China, not Piketty, Explains “Confused Signals” in U.S. Asset Prices
    The FT’s Ed Luce recently took on the “confused signals” being sent by U.S. stock and bond prices moving in sync (upward). Which is it, he asks?  Are economic prospects good, as stock prices suggest, or bleak, as bond prices suggest? Both and neither, he offers.  High-end retailers like LMVH and Tiffany are doing great, he says, while low-end ones like Walmart and Sears are languishing.  The net effect, he concludes, is stock prices buoyed by high-end earnings optimism and bond prices supported by a hollowing out of the American middle class.  Growing inequality explains the apparent conundrum. Given the current fascination with all things Piketty, this makes a charming and topical story.  But it is also almost certainly wrong. The straight average of U.S. company stock prices in the S&P Global Luxury index is actually down 1% this year; market-cap weighted, it’s up only 3.9%.  This compares with a 6.1% rise in the S&P overall.  As for Luce’s example of Tiffany (LMVH is foreign), its stock price has lagged mid-range retailer Macy’s.  In short, there is no discernable Piketty effect in U.S. stock prices. As for bond prices, China’s central bank holds the key. After more than three years of steady appreciation, the RMB has declined over 3% this year – erasing the past year’s rise.  Driven by the Chinese government’s desire to re-juice failing economic growth, RMB depreciation has naturally been accompanied by an increase in China’s foreign exchange reserves. China usually allocates about 40 percent of its foreign exchange reserves to Treasuries; so far this year, however, its official holdings of Treasuries have actually declined.  What explains this?  Given that China comes under pressure from the U.S. Treasury and Congress whenever it appears to be pushing down its currency, China is almost certainly disguising its Treasury purchases by holding them in Belgium. As shown in the graphic above, “Belgium” accumulated abnormal amounts of Treasuries during the first quarter of the year; Brussels-based clearinghouse Euroclear has acknowledged that it is likely responsible for the increase.  China’s actions would help explain why Belgium, a country whose GDP is slightly smaller than that of New Jersey's, has become the world’s third largest holder of Treasuries, after only China and Japan. China and “Belgium” bought a massive combined $59 billion in Treasuries in January, a month in which the supply of Treasuries actually shrank by $42 billion.  This would almost surely explain a large part of the decline in Treasury yields that month from 3.03% to 2.64% In short, the “confused signals” in U.S. asset prices would appear to be driven by China’s efforts to push down the RMB, and not by Pikettification of the U.S. economy. Financial Times: Look to China for Reasons Behind Strong Demand for Treasuries New York Fed: Responses to Survey of Primary Dealers Treasury: Major Foreign Holders of Treasury Securities Wall Street Journal: China Is in No Rush to Halt Yuan’s Fall   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Europe and Eurasia
    Global Economics Monthly: June 2014
    Bottom Line: Low inflation may be symptomatic of deeper problems, such as inadequate demand or central bank policy failures. The costs of low inflation could be high for European economies. There is a new Washington consensus, and it consists of a simple message: low inflation threatens the global economy. A weak and disappointing economic recovery feeds the concern, especially at a time when inflation is below targets and near zero in many countries. When did price stability change from a goal to a problem? Is too little inflation a symptom or cause of what ails us? Throughout the industrial world, debate rages over the causes and meaning of the chronically low inflation in the major industrial economies. Since the end of the Great Recession, central banks have seen inflation fall below their targets, despite unorthodox monetary policy aimed at jump-starting demand. Inflation is well below 2 percent in the Group of Three, or G3 (United States, Japan, and the eurozone), as well as in some Asian emerging markets. Though G3 inflation surveys show expectations anchored around 2 percent, bond yields have fallen this year as market participants bet on very low inflation going forward. These low market interest rates now seem at odds with the surveys. Central banks have responded with rate cuts (European Central Bank), quantitative easing (Bank of Japan), and commitments to keep rates low and raise them only gradually over time (Federal Reserve, Bank of England). In the case of the European Central Bank (ECB), President Mario Draghi has cited the "pernicious negative cycle" of low inflation and tight credit conditions as the central reason for recent easing moves. Whether accurate or not, this line of argument has built a consensus for action on the ECB board. Meanwhile, Federal Reserve governors point to the lack of inflationary pressures as evidence that easy monetary policy contains little risk to price stability. So, while central bankers continue to predict their policies will return inflation to target, there is little doubt that the shortfalls are influencing the policy debate. Low Inflation, Not Deflation There is a venerable body of economic analysis on the pernicious nature of deflation, which is usually defined as the broad-based, self-reinforcing decline in prices across an economy. When a country faces deflation, falling real wages and income weaken demand, dampen investment, and undermine confidence. The Great Depression in the United States and the Japanese experience with deflation after 1990 are often cited as evidence of the high cost of deflation and the challenge of ending it. Deflation was a significant risk coming out of the financial crisis of 2008/2009, and it took determined action by central banks to put those fears to rest. However, aside from a few countries on the periphery of Europe, there is little evidence of actual deflation in the industrial world today. At the same time, the stickiness of prices at near-zero levels is hard to explain. Most analysts expected that inflation would remain low for a while after the crisis, given the depth of the recession and the headwinds to recovery from damaged balance sheets and housing markets. Indeed, the sizeable economic slack that resulted was a central driver of the unconventional monetary policies adopted subsequently. But most public and private forecasters predicted prices would have begun to rise by now as recoveries reduced the amount of underutilized resources in the economy and put upward pressure on wages and goods prices (see Figure 1). Figure 1. Projections Predicted Rising Inflation Rates Sources: Federal Reserve, Eurostat How much should we be concerned about prices rising at around 1 percent annually? After all, while price stability is generally accepted as a good thing, and high inflation clearly destructive, there is little actual evidence that small differences in inflation make a big difference for economic growth. If 2 percent inflation is seen as price stability, is 1 percent inflation less efficient? The answer would appear to depend on the reasons for the shortfall. Low Inflation: Why Worry? One of the concerns regarding low inflation is that the economy is just one shock away from deflation. From this perspective, and given that monetary policy operates with "long and variable lags," some buffer against that risk makes sense. Beyond that, low inflation is perhaps symptomatic of a more fundamental problem of inadequate demand, and reflects the failure of the United States, Europe, and Japan to have a more significant liftoff in growth. A second set of concerns relate to worrisome signals to markets when central banks cannot hit targets. An inability to control the inflation rate could indicate that central banks have the wrong economic model, or that they are underestimating the damage caused by the Great Recession. Over time, missing targets can undermine the credibility of the central bank and the effectiveness of its policies. On the other hand, it is worth remembering that, before the euro, the Bundesbank missed its monetary targets about half the time, yet still was seen as highly credible. One reason why central banks might get the outlook wrong is by misestimating the downward structural pressures that result from globalization and demographic changes. The increasing effect of emerging markets on competition and deflation is widely appreciated, and may continue to exert downward pressure on prices even as growth in these countries' trade shares slows. But there is also a cyclical element to the story. In the case of Europe, I would argue that low inflation reflects a too-tight policy from the ECB and an incomplete monetary union, even after last week's rate cuts. But it is much harder to make the case that the policies of the Bank of Japan (following the introduction of Abenomics in early 2013) and the Fed have been too tight. Indeed, in recent months a number of market analysts have highlighted early indications that U.S. prices are moving up. The International Monetary Fund (IMF) has been in the vanguard, arguing that the costs of low inflation could be high globally, particularly for Europe. The arguments against too-low inflation in Europe are threefold: low inflation raises the real burden of the debt and increases real interest rates (interest rates net of inflation) to levels too high for full employment; it prevents the adjustment of relative prices across the eurozone, delaying the needed improvement in competitiveness and rebalancing of demand toward the periphery; and it can destabilize market expectations for future inflation. Without an ability to adjust their exchange rates against other countries in the currency union, and against the backdrop of extremely high government debt levels coming out of the recession, Europeans face a protracted period of low growth that can justify aggressive action from the ECB. Beyond Europe, prominent economists such as Paul Krugman and Larry Summers argue that there may be a long-term problem of inadequate demand. Citing the "secular stagnation" theory of Alvin Hansen, they argue that as a result of weak long-term growth and demand (in part a result of demographic trends that are shifting down the growth in the labor force), interest rates cannot go low enough in real terms to achieve full employment. Their policy prescription involves easier fiscal policy to boost demand and, perhaps, a Federal Reserve that keeps rates low for longer. It is hard to distinguish structural stagnation, which could be long-lasting, from "headwinds" from the financial crisis, including damaged consumer and bank balance sheets, and weak housing and labor markets. These headwinds will continue to recede as markets heal and balance sheets are repaired. In this regard, the U.S. economy is much further along than Europe, where deleveraging and bank cleanups are far less advanced, notwithstanding the progress made this year with the stress test and asset quality review. Globally, there is some evidence for the headwinds thesis in the stabilization (and in some cases increases) in commodity prices and trade. Both had been weak following the recession, contributing to deflationary pressures. Inflation now looks more likely to be driven by traditional cyclical factors in the future, including slack in labor and product markets. In the United States, we see this shift in a renewed debate over how close we are to full employment, following a series of strong employment reports. Economists are divided over whether continuing high rates of long-term unemployment will continue to exert downward pressure on wages, or whether the figure that matters most is the short-term unemployment rate, which is closing in on levels usually associated with an uptick in inflation. What should be done? Overall, I am drawn to the conclusion that, outside Europe, low inflation is more symptom than cause of low growth. I am sympathetic to the notion that low inflation in normal circumstances makes the policy response to a recessionary shock more challenging, because it is difficult to lower real rates sufficiently. From this perspective, a higher inflation target (Olivier Blanchard and others have called for a 4 percent target) has merit, though it is hard to see how central banks can credibly explain that shift to their publics. Whether there is any hard evidence that a 2 percent inflation target is best, it appears likely that policymakers will have to continue aiming for that level. Fortunately, central bank reflationary policies do appear to be working. With inflationary prospects beginning to diverge across the major regions, this suggests that monetary policies will also diverge—with further easing required in Europe and Japan, and normalization in the United States. Over the longer term, we once again may discover value in low inflation and price stability. Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon New Rules for Banks Announcements from U.S. regulators, including on the Volcker rule, will put meat on the new regulatory structure; foreign banks are unlikely to be pleased by tight restrictions on proprietary investment. Is Abenomics on Course? Japan's economic package will confirm the coming corporate tax cut, but will likely disappoint those looking for aggressive support for the economy. World Cup Economics A long World Cup run can be bad for a country's gross domestic product. But could an early Brazilian exit this year fuel discontent over poor growth and economic policies?
  • Europe and Eurasia
    Mr. Draghi, Tear Down These Rates!
    ECB President Mario Draghi was able to stabilize Eurozone nominal lending rates, which had been climbing dangerously in the periphery countries, with his famous do “whatever it takes” speech in July 2012.  Real (inflation-adjusted) lending rates for nonfinancial businesses, however, have risen steadily since then; in Spain, they are back up to their 2009 euro-era peak, as the right-hand figure in today’s Geo-Graphic shows. Draghi recently characterized deflation, or rather “internal devaluation,” in the crisis-hit periphery countries as “crucial adjustments vis-à-vis other euro area countries” – adjustments which “have to take place irrespective of changes in the external value of the euro,” which have been substantial (upward) over the past two years.  In the same speech he said that low private lending levels in such countries were unsurprising because of “weak credit demand,” which “in the early stages of an economic recovery is not unusual.” He acknowledged, however, that “targeted measures” could be necessary “to help alleviate credit constraints” if such constraints “impair the effects of our intended monetary stance.” We would suggest that he’s got things backwards.  With inflation having fallen to 0.5% in May, it is the monetary stance itself that is constraining credit demand by pushing down inflation expectations and pushing up the real cost of credit. Draghi should forget about “targeted measures,” and instead take broad, bold action to boost inflation expectations and tear down the wall of credit costs holding back the recovery. Wall Street Journal: Eurozone Inflation Slows, Jobless Rate Falls Financial Times: Eurozone Inflation Falls to 0.5% Economist: Draghi Spells It Out Bloomberg: Euro Inflation Slowing More Than Forecast Pressures ECB   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Global
    Can a Rule-Based Approach to Monetary Policy Enhance Economic Growth and Stability?
    Play
    Philadelphia Fed President Charles I. Plosser joins Joyce Chang of J.P. Morgan to discuss his views on monetary policymaking. Plosser advocates for a systematic monetary policy in which discretion and judgment are replaced by a more rule-based approach of reacting in predictable ways to particular economic conditions.
  • Global
    Can a Rule-Based Approach to Monetary Policy Enhance Economic Growth and Stability?
    Play
    Philadelphia Fed president Charles Plosser joins Joyce Chang of J.P. Morgan to discuss his views on monetary policymaking. Plosser advocates for a systematic monetary policy in which discretion and judgment are replaced by a more rule-based approach of reacting in predictable ways to particular economic conditions.
  • Europe and Eurasia
    Should the ECB Go on a Bund Buying Spree?
    Should the European Central Bank finally join the Fed, the Bank of England, and the Bank of Japan and deliver a good, stiff dose of Quantitative Easing? Maybe, came the surprise response from the hawkish Bundesbank president on March 25.  But “any private or public assets that we might buy,” Jens Weidmann warned, “would have to meet certain quality standards.” That’s a big but, as the quality of Eurozone assets has deteriorated markedly since 2009.  In fact, as today’s Geo-Graphic shows, if the ECB were to limit its asset purchases to the universe of AAA-rated Eurozone sovereign debt and securitized assets a whopping 80% of the total available would be German Bunds. But would a Eurozone QE program focused on gobbling up Bunds be such a bad idea?  We don’t think so. First, it might actually play a useful role in helping to eliminate structural imbalances within the Eurozone by pushing up German prices and wages disproportionately.  “While buying Greek or Portuguese paper could help tame deflation there,” an unnamed Eurosystem official recently told Reuters, “the falling consumer prices in these countries were part of a natural adjustment of their economies to become more competitive, and were actually welcome.” Second, through the so-called portfolio-balance effect the prices of other Eurozone assets will also be pushed up (and their yields down) as Eurozone banks replace the Bunds they sell to the ECB with other securities.  The Fed’s purchases of Treasurys and MBS most surely boosted asset prices across the spectrum in the United States (and abroad – just ask the ever-voluble Brazilian finance minister); the effect should be similarly broad in Europe. Finally, if a AAA focus for Eurozone QE were the price of getting Germany on board politically, it would be a small price to pay. Mario Draghi’s 2012 pledge to do “whatever it takes” remains in the background should he ultimately feel the need to operationalize OMT (Outright Monetary Transactions) and push down sovereign yields in Spain, Portugal, Italy, or elsewhere. Financial Times: ECB Policymakers Plot QE Road Map Bernanke: Monetary Policy Since the Onset of the Crisis The Economist: Turning Over a New Leaf? Bloomberg: Weidmann, Citing QE Legitimacy, Paves Way for ECB Consensus   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Europe and Eurasia
    IMF Reform and Ukraine: Amateur Hour for U.S. Economic Diplomacy
    In our March 5 post, we argued that the Obama administration linking Ukraine aid to IMF reform was disingenuous and counterproductive.  We were right: the legislation failed, congressional Republicans were angered, foreign governments were annoyed, and aid was delayed.  All for what?  Without IMF reform, Ukraine will still get every penny it would have gotten with IMF reform.  Today’s Geo-Graphic shows this.  And more... The far left two bars (1 and 2) in the figure show that IMF “Rapid Financing Instrument” (RFI) aid was precluded by the American political wrangling, which held up the $1 billion in U.S. loan guarantees the IMF expected to accompany RFI aid.  Bars 3 and 4 show the level of IMF aid Ukraine is entitled to over two years under “normal” access criteria with its current quota and what it would have been entitled to with a revised quota, post-IMF reform.  The difference between these two numbers is meaningless – even if IMF reform were enacted, Ukraine would still need to qualify for “exceptional” access to receive the level of aid the IMF has agreed to provide over two years (bar 5). Brazilian IMF executive director Paulo Nogueira Batista told the FT that he had wanted the Fund to approve a small bridging loan to Ukraine quickly, with negotiation of the bigger package coming later under less stress.  “The experience we had in some other programmes – notably Greece – is that rushed decisions taken under economic and political pressure can lead to questionable results.” But, he explained, Ukraine’s short-term financing needs were greater than the IMF could have covered with a bridging loan.  The U.S. loan guarantees could have covered the difference, but the Obama administration unwisely made them hostage to IMF reform. The scorecard?  No IMF reform; an unnecessarily rushed IMF aid package for Ukraine, but with slower aid dispersal; and ruffled feathers all around.  This is an object lesson in how not to conduct economic diplomacy. Financial Times: IMF Rushes Through $15 Billion Ukraine Bailout IMF: Agreement with Ukraine on US$14-18 Billion Stand-By Arrangement Wall Street Journal: IMF Reaches Deal to Provide Up to $18 Billion to Ukraine The Hill: Reid Drops Ukraine Demands   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Global
    On the Road to Recovery, or Creating the "Mother of All Bubbles"?
    Play
    With the tapering of the Federal Reserve's bond buying program well underway, and the possibility of future interest rate hikes under discussion, J.P. Morgan's Joyce Chang and Nouriel Roubini of Roubini Global Economics assess the risks that exist in the current global financial system in a discussion with CFR's Sebastian Mallaby.
  • Global
    On the Road to Recovery, or Creating the “Mother of All Bubbles”?
    Play
    With the tapering of the Federal Reserve's bond buying program well underway, and the possibility of future interest rate hikes under discussion, J.P. Morgan's Joyce Chang and Nouriel Roubini of Roubini Global Economics assess the risks that exist in the current global financial system in a discussion with CFR's Sebastian Mallaby.