Economics

Monetary Policy

  • Monetary Policy
    “It’s (Still) the Inflation, Stupid.”
    Fed officials have been tripping over themselves and each other trying to explain to the world what the right measure of unemployment is and how it should affect what the Fed does. Using the headline unemployment rate (“U-3”) in official communications hasn’t worked out so well.  Last June, then-Chairman Ben Bernanke suggested that the taper would end with U-3 around 7%; in fact, taper only started with U-3 below that level, at 6.6%.  The FOMC’s December 2012 forward guidance specified a 6.5% threshold for potential rate rises; yet now, with unemployment barely above this, we have NY Fed President Bill Dudley arguing that the guidance should be discarded entirely, as the number is “not providing a lot of value right now in terms of our communications.” No kidding.  And that’s because, as we argued in this post, it’s actually not about unemployment right now – whether the “right” measure is U-3, U-4 (adding discouraged workers), U-5 (adding all marginally attached workers), or U-6 (adding all marginally attached and employed-part-time-for-economic-reasons workers).  As the graphic above shows, unemployment today is not much above where it was when the Fed started hiking in ’94.  And the evidence is strong that unemployment is on a downward trend.  (The main debate is over how rapid the decline will be.)  Inflation, however, is way below the Fed’s official long-term target of 2%.  It is also substantially below where it was at the beginning of the Fed’s past four rate hike episodes - ’94, ’97, ’99, and ’04. This suggests not just that Dudley is right about the Fed dropping the U-3 guidance, but that the Fed should replace it with clarification on inflation.  At what point does the Fed worry about inflation going, or staying, too low?  Is the December 2012 inflation guidance, which said that the Fed would tolerate projected inflation 0.5% above its long-term target of 2% in order to bring unemployment down, still operative?  Or are we back to the plain-old 2% target?  Something else? It’s on inflation that the Fed appears disconcertingly rudderless at the moment. New York Fed: Eight Different Faces of the Labor Market Real Time Economics: The Evolution of the Bank of England’s Rate Guidance Davies: The Fed’s Next Focus Is on Wages Free Exchange: The Market Does Not Expect Overshooting   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Europe and Eurasia
    “The Euro Crisis Is Dead! Long Live the Euro Crisis!”
    You’ve got to hand it to Mario Draghi.  Never in the history of central banking has one man accomplished so much with so few words and even less action. Since having announced the creation of the Outright Monetary Transaction (OMT) program in August 2012, Draghi has had the pleasure of sitting back and watching yield spreads between Spanish and German government bonds fall relentlessly without having to buy a single bond.  Italian spreads have done the same. If only it were this easy to repeat the trick for unemployment, the spread for which has widened steadily over this period—as shown in the graphic above. Not surprisingly, Spaniards are unimpressed with the eurozone’s contribution to the country’s well-being.  According to a recent Pew survey, only 37% of Spaniards think the Spanish economy has been strengthened by European economic integration.  The corresponding figure in Italy and Greece is a mere 11%. Here’s the rub.  Draghi himself seems to believe that such economic integration is an important element in the eurozone’s long-term survival—central bank action is not enough. This is why OMT assistance is actually conditional on the country being on an EU-approved reform program.  “There are clear limits to what monetary policy can and should aim to achieve,” he told an audience in Munich last February.  “We cannot solve deep-rooted problems in the structure of Europe’s economies.” The euro crisis is not over. The Guardian: Spain's Unemployment Rise Tempers Green Shoots of Recovery Financial Times: Spain's Blockbuster 10-Year Bond Raised Draghi: The Policy and the Role of the European Central Bank During the Crisis Draghi: Introductory Remarks at the French Assemblée Nationale   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Monetary Policy
    Which Fed Guidance Should We Believe?
    In October 2012, the Fed issued what came to be called a “pledge” to keep its target interest rate near zero through mid-2015.  The market immediately reacted as the Fed wanted, centering expectations on a rate hike in mid-2015. At its next meeting, the Fed abandoned date-based guidance in favor of data-based guidance: a pledge to keep rates near zero until the unemployment rate fell below 6.5%.  The Fed emphasized, however, that the two pledges were consistent, as it didn’t expect unemployment to fall below that level until mid-2015. The Fed justified the shift from date-based to data-based guidance by stating that the latter “could help the public more readily understand how the likely timing of an eventual increase in the federal funds rate would shift in response to unanticipated changes in economic conditions and the outlook.” But has it? Fast forward, and the unemployment rate has been falling much faster than the Fed anticipated back then; the Fed now expects it to dip below 6.5% later this year.  Yet the market has revised its rate expectations in the opposite direction; it now believes a hike will not come until late 2015. For its part, the Fed has said nothing to nudge the market toward its amended (data-based) guidance; in fact, it is now suggesting that rates are likely to stay low “well past the time” the unemployment rate reaches 6.5%. Chairman Bernanke had in June of last year also indicated that QE3 monthly asset purchases could be expected to end when unemployment hit 7%, whereas a tapering of asset purchases is only now just starting with unemployment at 6.7%. All this suggests that the Fed’s experiment with data-based guidance is a flop. The 6.5% guidance may have been announced to help the public understand how the Fed would respond to “unanticipated changes in economic conditions,” but the Fed appears to have buried it because the unanticipated changes in the unemployment rate came about for unanticipated reasons – in particular, a big drop in the labor force participation rate. Before the Fed moves on to the next generation of guidance markers, it ought to think twice about the risks of worsening, rather than improving, the signal-to-noise ratio in its communications.  The jolt to the bond markets from the chairman’s unanticipated taper talk last May suggests what’s at stake as the Fed reverses the trajectory of policy from accommodation to tightening. New York Fed: Primary Dealer Surveys Federal Reserve: Minutes from the December 11–12, 2012 FOMC Meeting Financial Times: Four Problems That Question the Efficacy of Forward Guidance Hilsenrath: Jobs Report Alone Unlikely to Alter Fed’s Course   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”  
  • Monetary Policy
    Fischer to the Fed
    President Obama announced that he intends to nominate Stan Fischer, the former head of Israel’s central bank, to serve as the vice chairman of the Federal Reserve.  It also was announced that he would nominate Lael Brainard, the former Treasury undersecretary for international affairs, and would renominate current Fed Governor Jerome Powell to another term on the Fed Board.  The moves had been expected--nonetheless, it is worth celebrating an excellent set of appointments.  Stan Fischer is one of the leading macroeconomists and economic policymakers of our generation, and the Fed is fortunate to have him.  (Full disclosure--Stan is a former professor of mine, and currently a colleague at CFR.)  Jerome Powell has, by all accounts, played an important role at the Fed, and Lael Brainard brings a wealth of international policy experience to the position. I have been critical of the slow pace of White House appointments on the economic side.  It was particularly important to move on this, because once Bernanke leaves and until these nominations are confirmed by the Senate, only four of the seven Fed Board seats would be filled (one of whom, Powell, would not be confirmed during that period).  That would, among other things, create an imbalance vis-a-vis the district bank presidents (five of whom vote at meetings of the Federal Open Market Committee).  Well done, and I hope they are rapidly confirmed.
  • Budget, Debt, and Deficits
    Five Policy Issues for 2014
    Earlier this week I highlighted five issues that could prove particularly thorny for international economic policymakers this year.  They were: – A further sharp depreciation of the yen, in a scenario where the Bank of Japan needs to double down on quantitative easing (QE) to achieve it’s two percent inflation target. – A widening of external imbalances notably in Germany and China. – Market anxiety over the ongoing litigation in Argentina and the ongoing public debate over the rules of the game for debt restructuring. – The debate triggered by Paul Krugman and Larry Summers among others over whether the United States is suffering from “secular stagnation” that requires extraordinary demand policies to restore full employment. – The vast number of potentially headline-grabbing emerging market elections that, more than concern about Federal Reserve tapering, will be a focus for investors in those countries. Of the five, I have received the most push back on the Japan question, where many believe that current stimulative policies and a solid wage round will sustain demand in 2014 and more than offset the increase in the consumption tax this April.  I am not so sure. Robbie Feldman of Morgan Stanley, for example, tells a convincing story for QE2, where a loss of political and economic momentum, and the drag from the second (fiscal) and third (structural) arrows pose downside risks for inflation and growth. I am confident that should the expansion and inflation (and inflationary expectations) falter, the Bank of Japan has substantial scope to boost Japanese government asset purchases and extend its forward guidance in order to achieve the two percent target. In a weak domestic demand environment, the exchange rate would be a powerful channel through which that additional stimulus would operate. How would a yen of 120 or 130 against the dollar play out in the policy debate? Certainly it will create problems for the U.S. Treasury in current Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) negotiations, as well as for G20 efforts to limit exchange rate volatility. The broader problem is the risk of competitive measures—devaluation and capital controls—from other countries. So far, capital controls has been the dog that has not barked. But with central bank policies increasingly desynchronized, that could change in 2014. The U.S. Treasury also needs to move quickly to nominate and have confirmed a new Undersecretary for International Affairs.  Lael Brainard stepped down in early November, and the position remains unfilled.  This makes it all the more difficult for the U.S. to show the necessary leadership on these issues.
  • Global
    Federal Reserve Policy and Emerging Markets
    In his testimony before the House Committee on Financial Services' Subcommittee on Monetary Policy and Trade, Benn Steil argues that changes in U.S. monetary policy can have significant impact on emerging-market capital inflows and outflows and that the resulting exchange rate movements against the dollar can have large and rapid effects on the level of inflation and exports.
  • Monetary Policy
    Global Economics Monthly: January 2014
    After a year in which U.S. policy dominated the headlines, 2014 should have a more international flavor. Though not predictions, here are five economic themes that could make policymaker's lives difficult in 2014. 1. Catch a Falling Yen "Abenomics" has rejuvenated growth in Japan, but policymakers elsewhere continue to worry about what it means for the yen. Monetary stimulus—and more specifically the commitment to 2 percent inflation—remains the most powerful of the policy's "three arrows" (the others being fiscal and structural policies), and hopes for easier monetary policy were immediately reflected in a weaker yen. Since December 2012, the yen has fallen 17 percent against the dollar and 13 percent on a trade-weighted basis, with the current rate at 105 yen to the dollar. While it is possible that the upcoming wage round will provide a durable boost to incomes and inflation, there is growing concern that by mid-2014 the economy could begin to slow and deflationary pressures reemerge. Last month I argued that the Bank of Japan would "do whatever it took" to achieve its inflation target, which in this case means doubling down on its quantitative easing program. Where would that take the yen? A yen-to-dollar rate of 120 or 130 would cause significant stress in finance ministries around the world, given concerns about growth and exchange-rate instability. In addition to a rise in protectionist pressures, the resultant deflationary pulse among Japan's trading partners would intensify incentives for competitive depreciations. For U.S. policymakers, pressure is mounting from Congress to include exchange rate legislation as part of any trade agreement with Asia (the Trans-Pacific Partnership) or Europe (the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership). A sharp yen decline will intensify this debate. The issue is no less fraught in emerging markets, which are already buffeted by capital outflows over concerns about Federal Reserve tightening. Pressure to impose capital controls or engage in competitive depreciations is likely to mount. In 2013, the Group of Seven (G7) and Group of Twenty (G20) had a simple mantra: policies should be aimed at domestic objectives, and governments should not purchase foreign instruments (no direct foreign-exchange intervention). It is possible that 2014 will test that consensus. 2. Debalancing and Deleveraging In the economic context, "rebalancing" is not a pivot in U.S. foreign policy to Asia (at least not explicitly). Rather, it reflects U.S.-led efforts since the fiscal crisis in 2008 to encourage policies that will reduce global economic imbalances, most notably reflected in large current account surpluses and reserve accumulation. After several years of shrinking imbalances, 2014 looks to be the year that external trade surpluses for China and Germany begin to widen again (see Figure 1). This change reflects growth differentials, in part, and in normal times could be addressed through expansionary fiscal policy or an easing of financial conditions by central banks. But these are not normal times. China's early steps toward market liberalization will be tempered by the need to address the challenge of reining in its shadow banking system, and the risks to imports and growth remain on the downside. Meanwhile, Germany benefits from a euro that, while too strong for periphery countries struggling to restore competitiveness, is much weaker than it would be if Germany were not in a monetary union. A muted recovery in the rest of Europe is unlikely to provide a meaningful counterweight. The region continues to deleverage, and tighter credit conditions in the European periphery are likely to provide a substantial headwind to growth. In this context, concerns about global growth may intensify the rebalancing debate. Figure 1. German Trade Surpluses (in billions of euros) Sources: Haver and Bank of America Merrill Lynch Global Research estimates. 3. Argentina Fallout Argentina's standoff with its private creditors is now in front of the U.S. Supreme Court and may not be decided until 2015. Along with an ongoing reassessment of Greece's 2012 restructuring, the dispute has triggered a broader debate over whether the rules of the game for sovereign debt need to change. Some law and economics experts have argued that a decision against Argentina will, by strengthening creditor rights, swing the pendulum excessively toward creditors at a time when political and economic factors already make for restructurings that are "too little, too late." These critics contend that the process for restructuring sovereign debt—primarily through market-based debt exchanges—needs to change to make it easier to get deals done and prevent holdouts from blocking them. These changes could include new language in bond contracts, as well as changes to when and under what conditions the International Monetary Fund (IMF) lends to countries in distress. I am not convinced that the current system needs fixing; however, a full-throated official sector debate in 2014, combined with growing pressure on European policymakers to address official debt relief (OSI) for over-indebted periphery countries, has the potential to create tremendous uncertainty in markets, raising the risk of early runs on countries that are seen as candidates for official support. 4. Secular Stagnation, Quantitative Easing, and Inflation Targeting Larry Summers created a stir in November with his suggestion that the United States faces long-term secular stagnation. The idea that the weak recovery reflects structural factors—a global savings glut, investment uncertainty, or low productivity—suggests that real interest rates have to fall well below zero to produce an adequate recovery. In today's low inflation, recessionary environment, that is a tough challenge for central banks that cannot lower nominal interest rates below zero. If interest rates remain too high for an extended period, the resultant reduction in investment and increased unemployment has long-term effects: cyclical becomes structural. Fiscal policy can effectively boost demand in these situations—a point Summers elaborates on in the Washington Post. In the current U.S. policy environment, fiscal policy is hamstrung and monetary policy will have to carry the burden of supporting demand and reducing real interest rates. This could be done through higher inflation, which would require a change to current central banking orthodoxy (that inflation should be held to around 2 percent). Of course, central bank policy works through channels other than interest rates, including the exchange rate, equity, and housing prices. The argument also has been advanced by Paul Krugman, among others, and traces back to Alvin Hanson's "stagnation thesis." It contradicts the analysis of Ken Rogoff and Carmen Reinhart, among others, whose work identifies headwinds from a crisis that should recede over time. Somewhat perversely, these economists are looking at the United States at a time when the U.S. economy looks set to grow above trend this year. I find the case for secular stagnation more convincing for Europe. But the bottom line for Summers: one cannot assume a return to above-trend growth, and central banks may need to rethink how policy can and should be targeted. 5. Elections and Investors My colleague Jim Lindsay, CFR's director of studies, has highlighted elections to watch in 2014. Virtually all major emerging market governments face voters in 2014, including the so-called fragile five of Turkey (March and August), Indonesia (April), South Africa (April-June), India (May/June), and Brazil (October). Add in Colombia and Hungary, and 2015 elections in Ukraine and Argentina, and you have upcoming elections in nearly all of the major emerging markets. With U.S. fiscal and monetary policy on a steadier course following the recent budget deal and the Federal Reserve announcement that it would reduce (taper) its pace of government bond purchases, domestic factors are likely to again become the major drivers of market volatility. All of which could make for an interesting year. And it is even more important that there is strong leadership in the international economic arena, including in the United States, where critical Treasury positions remain vacant. Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon How Much Taper? Minutes from the Fed's December meeting will provide needed policy insight as Janet Yellen takes the reins. Europe Quantitative Easing The European Central Bank is expected to resist pressures to ease monetary policy in January, but odds are rising for more moves during the first quarter. Ultimately, qualitative easing will be necessary to produce above-trend growth. Emerging Markets Turmoil Political turmoil in Thailand and Ukraine, and ongoing concern about capital outflows, appear likely to provide a difficult start to the year in emerging markets.
  • Economics
    The Federal Reserve Tapers: In Search of Calmer Waters
    Yesterday’s decision by the Federal Reserve’s policy committee to modestly reduce (“taper”) its purchases of U.S. Treasury and mortgage-backed securities was a turning point in a number of respects.  After a long period of public debate that roiled markets, the Federal Reserve has at last begun what is likely to be a gradual and well-telegraphed exit from its period of extraordinary stimulus.  Together, last week’s fiscal deal and the Federal Reserve’s taper decision appears to have marked the start of a period of relative calm where U.S. macro policy uncertainty will be far less of a driver of markets. That’s good news for the global economy. A few observations on the decision. The decision yesterday to cut purchases by $10 billion to $75 billion represents a very small reduction in stimulus–worth just a few basis points on the long-term interest rate—and was easily offset by a more dovish statement and forecast for the future path of policy (“forward guidance”).  Equity markets rose on the announcement and Treasuries held their ground.  The Volatility Index (VIX), a measure of market uncertainty, fell 15 percent on the news. The Federal Reserve may see the response as reflective of its credibility; maybe, but it also reflects that the decision was significantly priced into markets and underscores the value to markets to resolving uncertainty. The path outlined by the Federal Reserve yesterday, a steady and gradual reduction in purchases (likely ending sometime in mid-to-late 2014) followed by a “liftoff” in rates sometime in 2015-16, means that policy remains highly accommodating and will only incrementally tighten. Even after purchases end, the Federal Reserve’s large balance sheet means that policy remains easier than if they had simply stopped when interest rates hit zero.  Policy remains data dependent, but one month or two of good data will not change this bottom line. Global inflation pressures remain muted and, given the amount of slack globally, is likely to not be a problem for policymakers in the near term.   The Bank of Japan will likely have to do more next year to meet their 2 percent inflation target.  The Federal Reserve’s move turns up the heat on the ECB—I expect we will see quantitative easing (QE) in Europe next year.  While Bernanke rightly highlighted that there were transitory factors helping to constrain inflation that could be reversed, the more likely scenario is that central banks will continue to worry more about deflation.  That too will introduce “stickiness” to policy. Looking ahead, forward guidance will be a relatively more important tool of policy, and QE less important.  This parallels a shift among economists—inside and outside the Fed—in thinking about what is most effective at influencing financial conditions.  Simply put, successive rounds of QE were less effective, relative to the potential benefits to credibly committing to maintain low rates for a long period. Forward guidance will be data dependent and markets will continue to price in changing expectations about the future.  But the payoff to clear commitments will tend to make policy changes more cautious and, hopefully, well telegraphed and therefore less noisy for markets. The Federal Reserve yesterday needed to address its former guidance that an unemployment rate of 6.5 percent was a threshold for considering a rate hike, something it may regret having said as the unemployment rate has fallen faster than expected. Some expected a lowering of the threshold to 6 percent, but the Federal Reserve instead shifted to a qualitative commitment:  “that it likely will be appropriate to maintain the current target range for the federal funds rate well past the time that the unemployment rate declines below 6-1/2 percent, especially if projected inflation continues to run below the Committee’s 2 percent longer-run goal.”  This was a clever way to get the message out while softening the focus on the unemployment rate going forward. As we know from its minutes and speeches, the Federal Reserve Board has been sharply divided on the question of tapering.  It should come together now.  Certainly there will be disagreements over how much to taper at any individual meeting and how to communicate, but these differences seem small compared to the debate that has played out over the past year.  It often has felt that Federal Reserve communication reflected as much a negotiation in public among Fed members as it was forward guidance to the public.  If so, this decision will make Janet Yellen’s communication task easier, and would be another reason why the taper decision was well timed. Over the past few years, both monetary and fiscal policy has been an extraordinary source of uncertainty.  Last week’s fiscal package took one set of risks off the table, and while the debt limit extension could be noisy (an increase is expected to be needed in March but could be stretched till May/June) the incentives for another crisis seem low for both parties. Now we have a monetary policy framework that markets seem to understand and welcome.  Together, the reduction in uncertainty could be quite constructive for investment and growth.
  • Monetary Policy
    "It's the Inflation, Stupid"
    “Based on labor market data alone, the probability of a reduction in the pace of asset purchases has increased,” said Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis President James Bullard on December 9.  Indeed, Fed watchers have been firmly focused on the improving labor market data in their handicapping of the prospects for an imminent Fed “taper” of its monthly asset purchases, known as “QE3,” which it began back in September 2012. Yet the Fed has a dual mandate, the second aspect of which, inflation, has been galloping away from the Fed’s target.  Indeed, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) justified the launch of QE3 by referring specifically to the need to “ensure that inflation, over time, is at the rate most consistent with its dual mandate.” And “inflation,” Bullard noted, “continues to surprise to the downside.” As the FOMC begins two days of meetings, we benchmark the Fed’s performance against each element of its mandate as well as a combination of the two.  As today’s Geo-Graphic shows, the Fed’s preferred inflation measure has been moving away from the Fed’s 2% target faster than unemployment has been declining towards the 5.6% midpoint of the Fed’s range of longer-run estimates.  Since QE3 began, inflation has declined from 1.7% to 0.7% (at its last reading in October) as unemployment has fallen from 7.8% to 7%.  As our small inlaid graphic shows, if the Fed were placing equal emphasis on inflation and unemployment there would be no grounds for beginning to taper its monthly asset purchases at this time—the Fed is today farther away from its dual-mandate benchmark than it was when it launched QE3 last year. Wall Street Journal: Fed Faces Tough Decision on Bond-Buying Financial Times: Strong U.S. Jobs Data Raise Expectations of Fed Taper Economist: Is QE Deflationary?   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Japan
    Global Economics Monthly: December 2013
    Bottom Line: Abenomics had an impressive start, but the structural reform agenda has bogged down, raising questions about whether macro policies alone can float the Japanese economy. Against the backdrop of geopolitical tensions with China and entrenched interests at home, now could be the time to go short on the Japanese economic miracle. Why the new pessimism about Abenomics? Launched to fanfare late last year, the policy's three "arrows"—monetary, fiscal, and structural—delivered impressive early returns. Growth rose above 2 percent from April to September, equities soared 50 percent between November and May, and a weaker yen boosted export competitiveness. But recent concerns over the government's commitment to structural reform, anxiety about a possible fiscal cliff in 2014, and rising political tension with China have dampened sentiment. Some analysts have even suggested that a Japanese debt crisis is an underappreciated potential black swan event for the global economy over the next few years. At the core, these developments confirm the limits of macroeconomic policy. Abenomics' shock easing of monetary policy, reinforced by a convincing commitment that policy will remain easy, was a clear and substantial break with the past. In parallel, a necessary and appropriately gradual rebalancing of fiscal policy allows the government to begin the process of consolidation while continuing to provide insurance against future downturns. Together, these macroeconomic policies will ensure a strong cyclical recovery. However, the trend growth rate of an aging and sclerotic Japan is unlikely to improve without effective structural reform. And, absent that change, sentiment may sag and an overwhelming government debt is likely to drag on economic performance. Arrow One: Straight and True Early optimism was clearly driven by monetary policy, the first of the three arrows highlighted by Prime Minister Shinzo Abe. The monetary policy arrow represented a sea change in policy: a commitment to eliminate decades of deflation and restore growth through unconventional monetary policy. The centerpiece of the policy was a commitment by the Bank of Japan (BOJ) to "two-by-two-by-two": inflation of two percent through a twofold increase in the balance sheet of the central bank (in effect, doubling the money supply) in two years (see Figure 1). The announcement combined an easy-to-understand commitment with a promise to keep rates low until the target is achieved—powerful "forward guidance" in the language of modern central banking. The promised monetary stimulus will not guarantee, by itself, the demand required to sustain 2 percent inflation, and recent BOJ minutes show concerns that household incomes are not keeping pace with higher consumer prices. Ultimately, success of the reflation agenda will depend on higher wages and incomes, overcoming opposition from business groups, and entrenched deflationary expectations. Officially, the Bank of Japan remains optimistic that inflation will pick up, based on a wage round that is underway and will be subject to a fair degree of moral suasion. There are good reasons to be skeptical about this rosy outlook, but there's also comfort in the fact that if inflation does not meet expectations, the Bank of Japan will buy more assets of longer duration and maturity than previously envisaged. The BOJ's own version of "do whatever it takes" remains the core building block of Abenomics. In return for this promise, Japanese corporations will need to deliver on wages. Figure 1. Central Bank Balance Sheets (in percent of GDP) Source: Estimates from the central banks and IMF; CME 2010 was BOJ's cumulative monetary easing exercise. Note: The BOJ's April 2013 forecast breaks with the past and may outperform other central banks. Arrow Two: Speed Bumps, Not Cliffs The second arrow of Abenomics, fiscal policy, remains a complex story. On one hand, a central tenet of the policy is fiscal consolidation over the medium term to reduce gross government debt that now stands at over 240 percent of gross domestic product (GDP). A gradual increase in the value-added tax (VAT) was the prime tool of that adjustment, which also advanced a structural agenda to shift the burden of taxation away from income and toward consumption. Conversely, fiscal stimulus at the start of Abenomics was a critical buffer for growth, ahead of the planned first increase in the VAT in spring 2014. Given concerns over debt sustainability, the decision to front-load fiscal stimulus was always a risky move and complicated the timing of a shift toward fiscal restraint. Prime Minister Abe's decision to go ahead with the consumption tax hike as scheduled similarly was contentious; market experts expressed concern about the effects of too-rapid fiscal consolidation on the recovery. In the end, the decision to go ahead with the hike and offset a portion of the resulting fiscal drag with discretionary stimulus looks to have struck the right balance between support for the recovery and long-run fiscal stability. The Observatory Group has a neat dissection of concerns that Japan faces a fiscal cliff in 2014. Their bottom line is a modest fiscal contraction in 2014, on the order of 1 percent of GDP. Arrow Three: Much Ado about Nothing (Yet) While recent news suggests the monetary and fiscal arrows remain on course, the news is not so good for the structural agenda. Several early efforts saw setbacks: a recent draft proposal for removing a ban on sales of over-the-counter drugs fell short of expectations, prolonging restrictions on more than two dozen popular medicines ( in some cases permanently). A taxi reregulation law and slow progress on national economic zones—hinting at past unsuccessful government efforts—have also raised concerns. Further, proposals for labor market and agricultural reform appear to have stalled. On the labor side, the government is targeting an increase in female labor-force participation, a laudable long-term goal that policy is likely to affect only gradually. The government also continues to place high importance on the successful conclusion of the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) with eleven other countries, including the United States, which is scheduled for agreement by year-end. But that agreement appears likely to be delayed, or watered down in areas such as agriculture that are crucial to Japan. A realistic assessment of the record must acknowledge that structural changes in the Japanese economy are usually the result of custom, not law. Consider, for example, proposed changes in the law to make it easier to hire and fire workers. Significant legal changes now look unlikely, and even if laws are passed, the rigidity of the labor market in Japan, reflecting custom and reinforced by culture, makes it difficult for firms to lay off workers. If Abenomics transforms labor markets, it will be because of the signals it sends that times are changing, rather than the literal change in laws. It is often said that structural reform of the Japanese economy to raise trend growth is the most critical to the long-term success of Abenomics. Though these reforms will have a limited impact on economic performance in the near term (that is the realm of macro policies), the debt dynamics will not be sustainable unless there is a material increase in the growth rate over time. Conversely, for those who believe that debt sustainability concerns are overblown because, for example, the debt is owned primarily by the Japanese themselves, a weak performance on the structural agenda may not be a devastating blow to the program. Robert Feldman of Morgan Stanley sees the recent slippage as the result of complacency as the government shifts its focus away from economics and toward security issues. Noting the recent decline in Prime Minister Abe's support to below 50 percent, Feldman looks toward an end to the complacency phase and wonders how long and deep the crisis will be before the prime minister responds with a renewed economic focus. Looking ahead It is almost a year since the world woke up to the prospect of Abenomics transforming Japan. Its success in bringing back inflation and boosting demand has been transformative. If success is measured by those criteria, Abenomics gets high grades, though it will present risks for policymakers globally. However, the hard choices on the structural agenda remain, and the government will need to show more courage than it has demonstrated recently. Markets seem largely unworried by the recent setbacks. After stalling out during the fall, Japan's equity market rose 6 percent in the last two weeks as the yen resumed depreciating against the U.S. dollar. Gains were led by financials and exporters and are most likely to benefit from improved trade prospects. The yen depreciated by around 3 percent, ending just above the 102-yen-per-dollar level for the first time since early September. Foreign purchases of domestic bonds have returned to levels recorded this summer. One explanation for benign market conditions is the argument that all that matters in the short term is monetary policy. For hedge funds in particular, a long-Nikkei/short-yen trade has worked well, and expectations that the BOJ will ease monetary policy further, possibly at a time when the Fed is cutting back on its stimulus (i.e., tapering), is reason enough for cheer (and for pushing speculative yen shorts to three-year highs). Another more subtle argument, as noted earlier, is that markets assume that Japan's high level of debt—and the constraints on policy it imposes—are less severe than the numbers suggest because of the high degree of domestic ownership. The argument goes that Japan can work out of its debt problems through a managed process of financial repression, lowering real returns on government assets to maintain a sustainable debt profile. That may be the case, but a crisis can materialize quickly if the assumption that domestic investors are willing to accept negative real returns proves false. Is Abenomics the "black swan" of 2014? Probably not. But structural reforms are likely to disappoint and the pressure will then shift to the BOJ to do more. A further easing of monetary policy will be a positive for growth, but means a weaker yen. At some point, coming against the backdrop of weak global growth, such policies could present global concerns and contribute to already strong tensions within the G20 about competitive depreciation, intervention, and capital controls. All this suggests that it could be an interesting 2015. Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon Fed Revisits Taper The December meeting, Bernanke's last, will renew debate over when the Fed begins to reduce its asset purchases. Emerging Market Debt Political turmoil in Ukraine raises default fears, and Argentina tries to settle nationalization claims. European Revival Credit upgrades for Greece and Spain do not signal a broad-based growth revival in Europe.
  • Europe and Eurasia
    ECB Rate Cut a No-Brainer; Also, for Many, a No-Gainer
    Back in April, we showed that the eurozone countries most in need of lower corporate borrowing rates benefited only marginally from ECB rate cuts. Today’s Geo-Graphic shows that little has changed in this regard; the financial crisis has clearly done serious and lasting damage to the monetary transmission mechanism in Europe – particularly as it affects Greece, Portugal, Spain, and Italy. In April we also showed that the GDP-weighted inflation rate of the countries where the monetary transmission mechanism was working normally – Austria, Finland, France, Germany, and the Netherlands – was 1.8%, right near the ECB’s target of just-below 2%. Thus, the countries that most needed lower borrowing rates needed much more than an ECB rate cut to boost business lending, whereas those where business lending was responsive to ECB rate cuts were not clearly in need of one – at least according to the ECB’s inflation criterion. Inflation in the strong countries, however, has declined significantly since then – it now stands at a GDP-weighted 1.5%. This means that a rate cut at the ECB’s November 7 governing council meeting should be a no-brainer. Sadly, our Geo-Graphic suggests it will also be a no-gainer; the ECB will have to take far more aggressive action to prod business lending in the worst-hit crisis states. Financial Times: ECB Weighs Up Options Amid Concerns Over Falling Prices Bloomberg News: Draghi Weighs Whether Rate Cuts Too Valuable as ECB Meets Wall Street Journal: A Call to Arms for the ECB The Economist: Waiting for the Cut   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Capital Flows
    Emerging Market Taperitis
    “In considering whether a recalibration of the pace of its asset purchases is warranted,” Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke offered back on May 22, the Fed “will continue to assess the degree of progress made toward its objectives in light of incoming information.” The reaction to this modest and heavily hedged statement in emerging-market currency and bond markets was swift and brutal. But the pain was not shared equally. As the top figure in today’s Geo-Graphic shows, those countries whacked hardest by taper-talk were those with large current-account deficits—Turkey, India, Indonesia, and Brazil. These nations had been cruising on the QE3, comfortably financing excesses of consumption over production with dollars desperately scouring the globe for return. But the mere hint of a QE3 docking was enough to send foreign investors into paroxysms of fear over depreciation and default risk. Not surprisingly, as the bottom figure shows, their currencies were also the biggest beneficiaries of last month’s taper-interruptus—the Fed’s decision to back away from a strongly hinted-at September pullback in asset buying. The message received in emerging markets was clearly not one the U.S. Treasury had wished to send—in good times, apply a firm hand to keep your imports and currency down, and exports and reserves up. The U.S. Congress may cry “manipulation!”, but history shows that this is a small price to pay for taperitis protection. Note: No data on Brazilian 10-year government bond prices are available from Bloomberg after July 2, 2013. Financial Times: Turkey Relieved at Fed Decision to Postpone Taper Beyondbrics: Ben Bernanke and Responsible Parenting Real Time Economics: Learning to Love the Fed Taper IMF: Global Impact and Challenges of Unconventional Monetary Policies   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • International Organizations
    Foreign Exchange Controls: Good or Bad for South Africa?
    This is a guest post by John Causey, a private equity consultant based in South Africa, who specializes in sub-Saharan Africa transactions. In a pithy headline Richard Grant, writing for Forbes Magazine, recently remarked that “It Cost Mark Shuttleworth More To Leave South Africa Than It Did To Leave The Earth.” The attention-grabbing headline, while technically accurate, requires explanation. Mark Shuttleworth, a noted South African philanthropist and venture investor, decided in 2009 to move his remaining cash positions out of South Africa. Through powers granted under exchange controls legislation, the South African Reserve Bank (SARB) imposed a levy of 10 percent (USD 30 million at that time). The case that followed was decided in favour of the SARB, and Shuttleworth’s arguments that exchange controls were an unconstitutional taking and that the method of enforcement deprived South Africans of due process were rejected by the courts. The levy payment of USD 30 million to the SARB remained, and that payment dwarfed the USD 20 million he paid to become the first African in space in 2002, giving Mr. Grant the fodder for the aforementioned Forbes headline. Exchange controls allow for the regulation of the manner in which capital flows into and out of a country, and while common on the African continent, they are scarcely seen in more developed economies. In South Africa, exchange controls were established many years ago, and were applied forcefully during the apartheid era to combat capital flight and to ease balance of payments pressures. Though not as rigidly enforced as in the past, they remain one of the vestiges of the Afrikaner Nationalist government, which the ANC has opted to not dismantle. Proponents of exchange controls argue that smaller economies are affected too greatly by developed world monetary policies (e.g., seemingly endless rounds of quantitative easing in the U.S.), and that controlling currency flows gives these economies more stability and independence. If free flows of capital were allowed, they argue, domestic monetary policy alone would be ineffective in staving off capital account deterioration, inflation and currency devaluation. As articulated in Shuttleworth’s suit, opposing views are largely political and fairness based, and the primary financial argument deals with discouraging investment. By taking away the ability to easily repatriate funds, a form of investment irreversibility is introduced that deters investors. Additionally, there is the administrative headache which Shuttleworth cites as a prime reason for running all of his philanthropic and other international activities outside of South Africa. Large institutions and banks in South Africa avoid these layers of red tape and levies by opening shell companies in countries like Mauritius to run their international operations. Though this solution works for large corporations, it comes at a cost of lost tax revenues and jobs to South Africa. Unfortunately, opening foreign shell companies isn’t a viable option for job creating small and medium sized enterprises who aspire to transact outside of the relatively small South African marketplace. For those cheering with Shuttleworth for the swift eradication of the controls, don’t hold your breath. There is a flood of bad economic news coming out of South Africa in the form of BMW halting future investment plans, Morgan Stanley labelling the country as a “Fragile Five,” the IMF and World Bank issuing warnings to the country, business leaders vocalizing dissatisfaction with the status quo and a seeming lack of progress in NDP implementation. For these and other reasons, it’s unlikely that the effects of such a move would net a positive near-term result and thus difficult to justify by either the government or SARB.
  • Europe and Eurasia
    Paul Krugman’s Baltic Bust—Part III
    Geo-Graphics posts in July 2010 and 2012 showed that Paul Krugman’s devaluation-driven “Icelandic Miracle” was nothing of the sort – a figment of his having chosen the most favorable possible starting date (Q4 2007) for his Baltic (and Irish) economic-performance comparisons.  Move it forward or back, and Krugman’s story collapses like a warming arctic ice shelf. Our 2012 post particularly upset him - the poor thing being so weary of having to deal with benighted economic illiterates.  In suggesting that Krugman look not just at how his four chosen countries had performed relative to their pre-crisis peaks, but how they had performed since they hit bottom, we were apparently guilty of knowing nothing about business cycles – which to Krugman’s mind means believing that positive output gaps can actually exist. Now that the IMF’s Olivier Blanchard, Mark Griffiths, and Bertrand Gruss have explained to him in a 39-page Brookings paper what we failed to get through to him in a simple sentence last year – that Latvia, whose inflation rate topped 15% in 2008, was producing well over its potential output at its pre-crisis GDP peak (undermining Krugman’s post-peak analysis) – Krugman has changed his tone on the Baltics abruptly. (One can’t credibly call Olivier Blanchard an idiot, now, can one?) Last year Krugman was peeved at having to defend his “Icelandic Miracle” claim against evidence that the competition had actually done as well or better, without devaluation; now, however, faced with more of the same evidence from a different source, he’s content just to quarantine Latvia as “a more or less unique case.” But let’s not quibble about esoterica like output gaps.  Let’s address Krugman’s “Icelandic Miracle” claim on his own terms – that is, let’s just update his very own post-peak “Icelandic Miracle” figure. Here it is, folks: Iceland, whose currency lost half its value against the euro in 2008, vs. Estonia, Latvia, and Ireland, all of which were euroized or pegged to the euro over the entire period . . . In the updated figure, Estonia comes out on top, by a lot – well above Iceland, which performed no better than Latvia or Ireland, even using a starting date chosen by Krugman to make Iceland look as good as possible. In short, Krugman credited Iceland’s post-crisis devaluation for an economic “miracle” that clearly never was. In fact, Iceland is now facing a new foreign-debt repayment crisis brought on by the capital controls Krugman extolled. Hark, O ye Greeks: Beware pundits touting miracles.  The floating krona didn’t bring one to Iceland, and the drachma won’t bring you one either.   Financial Times: Dissatisfied Icelanders Question Myth of Post-Crash Success VoxEU: The Collapse of Iceland's Banks Wall Street Journal: IMF Warns on Icelandic Economy   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Capital Flows
    Global Economics Monthly: October 2013
    Bottom Line: In the face of uncertain capital flows, an international network of swap lines would help to ensure adequate liquidity and act as a significant enhancement of the global financial safety net. Should the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and major central banks provide credit lines to countries facing sharp outflows of capital? In 2007, 2010, and 2011, the Federal Reserve's dollar-swap lines with other central banks played a critical role in stabilizing markets and ensuring an adequate supply of dollar liquidity. Now, in the context of sudden reversals of capital flows ("sudden stops"), there are proposals for new swap or credit arrangements for emerging markets and for the periphery of Europe. These proposals have their virtues, though perhaps not the ones their proponents claim. Swap Lines, the Fed, and the IMF The idea that the International Monetary Fund (IMF) should coordinate a global network of swap lines gained currency during the financial crisis, partly in response to complaints from countries excluded from the Fed's swap lines. The Fed's prudential concerns, along with a mandate to limit swaps to countries viewed as threatening global financial stability, highlighted gaps in the global safety net. In addition, the Fed's swap lines were temporary. The primary argument for a new arrangement rests on the observation that in today's financial markets—highly leveraged, complex, and interconnected—adequate liquidity is central to avoiding crisis. This suggests the need for something more comprehensive and permanent. This debate is not new. A group of Asian countries led by China launched a regional swap plan in 2010 (the Chiang Mai Initiative), and, in the run-up to the Seoul G20 Summit, the Koreans floated a proposal for a global network of swaps modeled on Chiang Mai. Around the same time, motivated in part by concern that the Asian arrangements would compete with it as a global financial authority, the IMF floated a proposal for an IMF-backed network of swaps. These proposals never gained broad support, and with the easing of the crisis the pressure for reform went away. The catalyst for renewed debate was the reversal of capital flows from emerging markets, beginning in June, based on expectations that the Fed would begin to exit from quantitative easing. The most developed proposal comes from Ted Truman, who in a recent piece calls for a global network of central bank swap lines coordinated by the IMF. Central banks would retain control over the lines, though the IMF would identify the need and decide when systemic risks warrant activation of the lines. The plan would be a significant enhancement of the global financial safety net, though the complexity of the proposal, the magnitude of the liquidity commitments it requires from central banks, and the central role it gives to the IMF are sure to raise opposition in major capitals. Emerging Markets: The Next Big Crisis? A number of emerging markets have seen a large capital outflow, precipitating sharp financial market moves and forcing a tightening of policies. Attention has focused in particular on the "fragile five"—Brazil, India, Indonesia, South Africa, and Turkey—countries with substantial financial markets, large current account deficits, and financial imbalances. But in other respects, it is hard to see these problems as the start of a systemic economic crisis. For example, in contrast to conditions at the time of the 1997 Asian financial crisis, most of these countries have substantially higher international reserves to act as a buffer against capital flow reversals. External imbalances are manageable and more of the debt is of longer maturity. Consequently, the risk of a sharp run on banks, which happened in Korea in late 1997, seems less likely. Markets have stabilized recently. Nonetheless, corporate and financial sector leverage remains high in many countries, posing an uncertain but continuing risk of runs. Precautionary and Contingent Credit Lines Still, it is hard to argue against the notion that countries should do more to get ahead of a possible crisis and prepare for contingencies. The IMF offers credit lines to countries vulnerable to global shocks but with otherwise strong policies.[1] However, the stigma associated with turning to the IMF has limited the use of those programs. In 2011, the IMF discussed the possibility of simultaneously offering credit lines to a group of countries as a way of overcoming resistance to these programs. The idea was that prequalifying countries would lessen the pain associated with having to approach the IMF for support. The problem with this idea is what to do when a country's policies worsen, or are subsequently seen as inadequate. Drawing on a credit line cannot be a substitute for necessary policy reform. Even so, I see a case for an expanded use of precautionary lines as a signal to markets and to strengthen a country's defenses against market turmoil. Progress is possible in the current discussion of how to support countries in the European periphery. Ireland and Portugal may request contingent credit lines from Europe's Economic Stabilization Mechanism (ESM) to help them exit their IMF-supported adjustment programs. In Ireland's case, a contingent line would be a transitional arrangement to signal to markets that the country continues to have European support. In Portugal's case, a new bailout is likely, though both the government and its European creditors are loath to admit it. As a consequence, European leaders appear resistant to provide a credit line to Portugal; that is a pity. Moreover, other countries in the periphery could benefit from contingent lines from the IMF. So what purpose do these credit lines serve? In practical terms the lines are the framework for the needed expansion of the safety net and for "more Europe." If this approach helps to achieve improved governance in Europe, then that would be a major step forward. More generally, a network of IMF-supported swap lines would strengthen the global safety net and provide an important buffer against future sudden stops in capital flows. Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon The Cliff Is Dead, Long Live the Cliff A U.S. government shutdown is in effect with no clear exit strategy. A far more material and potentially damaging standoff on the debt limit looms. The World Bank and IMF Meet Meetings later this week between the world's two major financial institutions will reveal anxiety about growth and capital flows, but offer little agreement on what to do about it. Abenomics' Second Arrow The issue is fiscal sustainability over the medium term, without killing growth now. The decision to go ahead with the consumption tax is good on structural grounds but has renewed growth fears. Endnotes ^ The two main programs are a flexible credit line (FCL) for countries whose policies would be adequate absent global financial market volatility, and a precautionary credit line (PCL) for those countries where some policy changes would be needed.