Economics

Monetary Policy

  • Europe and Eurasia
    The Politics of IMF Crisis-Country Growth Projections
    IMF GDP growth “projections” accompanying emergency lending programs are nothing of the sort; they are targets the level of which is necessarily set high enough to enable the interventions. Take Greece.  After committing to lending of €30 billion over 3 years in 2010, the Fund projected that the crisis-mired nation would return to growth by 2012.  As shown in the left figure above, Greece’s economy actually plunged by 7% that year – the year it completed the world’s largest sovereign restructuring, covering €206 billion of bonds. Take Ukraine.  After committing to lending $17 billion over 2 years in April, the Fund projected that its civil/Russian war would magically end and its economy bloom – achieving 2% growth in 2015.  Instead, its “adverse scenario” looks to be playing out according to script, with the economy on pace for a 7% decline.  There is now a massive $15 billion gap between what has been pledged by the official sector (IMF, World Bank, European Union, and others) and what is actually needed to fund the government. The point is not that the IMF is particularly incompetent or unlucky; few in the organization’s talented professional staff could be in the least surprised with how Greece and Ukraine have played out.  The point is that the IMF’s growth projections for crisis-hit client countries are deliberately being pegged at levels high enough to overcome its own prohibition against lending to countries that lack sufficient funding to cover government spending over the coming 12 months. This is a sound rule, intended to keep the Fund from getting sucked into the vortex of politics.  Greece’s insolvency clearly required write-offs and gifts; more debt, which is all the Fund has to offer, was never going to resolve the problem.  Ukraine requires at a minimum a cessation of hostilities.  By all means, the EU, U.S., and other friendly nations should step in financially and otherwise to show solidarity, but such is not the proper role of the Fund.  If it manages to avoid major losses on these interventions, it will only do so by having provided political cover for those who will – governments, such as those of Germany and the United States, which should have been up-front with their people about the likely cost and political purpose of their aid. Financial Times: IMF Warns Ukraine Bailout at Risk of Collapse Wall Street Journal: Ukraine Will Need More Bailout Funding, IMF’s Lagarde Says IMF: Ukraine Request for a Stand-By Arrangement IMF: Ex Post Evaluation of Greece's Exceptional Access   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Japan
    Global Economics Monthly: December 2014
    Bottom Line: Many experts hope that December snap elections will reenergize Japan’s structural-reform agenda, but the barriers to implementation remain high. Without progress on this “third arrow” of Abenomics, growth will remain almost fully dependent on easy money, intensifying global currency tensions in 2015. Most analysts are optimistic that this month’s elections in Japan could represent a turning point for the faltering Japanese economy. They argue a strong showing by Prime Minister Shinzo Abe’s Liberal Democratic Party (LDP) will provide a clear mandate to reinvigorate Abe’s structural-reform agenda. Indeed, the polls recently have moved in the LDP’s favor, and now suggest that the government could win well over three hundred seats in the lower house of parliament, nearly a two-thirds majority (the party currently holds 294 seats). Should Abe make economic reform a priority, he appears to have a mandate to make significant progress. Recall that structural reform was the ambitious third arrow of Abenomics, complementing monetary policy (the first arrow) and fiscal consolidation/reform (the second arrow). The government was committed to agricultural reform as part of a Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) agreement, as well as comprehensive labor and product market reforms. Many other governments, as well as market participants, linked their support for Abenomics to this third arrow in hopes of a supply-side effect that would allow a sustained increase in growth. To date, though, little has been accomplished. Given the continuing vested interests and political impediments to reform, my concern is that, though the government will “wave the flag” of structural reform in the coming months, the focus will quickly turn to domestic constitutional reform of the electoral system and regional defense concerns, sapping the energy behind economic reform. The fiscal arrow, in contrast, aimed to restore fiscal sustainability through upfront stimulus coupled with a multistage increase in the consumption tax. However, following weak growth numbers, the consumption tax has been delayed (though the government has committed to an increase in 2017). Although that makes a lot of sense on cyclical grounds, the government will still need to worry about fiscal credibility with government debt already in excess of 250 percent of gross domestic product (GDP). In that case, what is left to drive economic growth? Abenomics, which generated strong support based on its comprehensive three-arrow approach, would be reduced to a single arrow—aggressive monetary easing. A Sea Change for Monetary Policy Japan’s monetary policy is indeed extraordinary. At the end of October, by a five-to-four vote, the Bank of Japan (BOJ) surprised nearly everyone with a dramatic expansion of its unconventional monetary policy, citing renewed risks of deflation. If the program is fully implemented, bond holdings will be over 40 percent of GDP, adjusting for duration of the debt purchased, which is more than twice the size of the Federal Reserve’s three quantitative easing programs between 2008 and 2013. For a small, open economy such as Japan’s, easier money works in large part through the exchange rate. I would not argue that the central bank is aiming for exchange-rate depreciation, but at play is a central bank that—while motivated by domestic considerations—is taking advantage of the Fed’s turn toward normalization to make a dramatic move that ensures a substantial market impact by emphasizing the divergence of policy. As shown in Figure 1, the yen’s recent moves closely track movements in the Bank of Japan’s balance sheet. Japan has experienced sharp fluctuations in the past and there is reason to believe this time will be no different. Although some market commentators would argue that investors are already stretched, holding substantial investments that would do well in the case of a yen depreciation, from a fundamental perspective there is still some way for the yen to fall if the BOJ meets its asset-purchase targets. Still, Japan faces an uphill battle to reach its inflation target. A sharp and continuing decline in retail gasoline prices in yen, as well as the deflationary effect as the earlier consumption-tax hike wears off, has by some measures reduced underlying inflation to below 1 percent. Figure 1: The Dollar–Yen Exchange Rate and the Bank of Japan’s Balance Sheet Source: Bank of Japan; Oanda Exchange Rate Intervention In a coordinated announcement, the Japanese Government Pension Investment Fund (GPIF) announced a shift away from government bonds and toward equities, both domestic and foreign, doubling the share of equities to 50 percent. As a general rule it is not such a good idea to use government wealth funds as an instrument of monetary policy in this way: insurance and savings for future generations should be insulated from the short-term decisions that drive monetary policy. However, given that government policy has skewed previously toward support of the bond market, it can be argued that this is a good move from a longer-run perspective, and it does arguably strengthen the near-term wealth effects of quantitative easing. But it is worth highlighting that from an economic perspective, combining monetary easing with foreign asset purchases is the same as directly intervening in exchange markets, something the Group of Twenty (G20) has clearly opposed. In the context of weak global demand, it is unclear how Japan’s trading partners will respond to a sharp and continuing depreciation of the yen. To date, a number of Japan’s Asian trading partners have expressed concern, but we have not seen significant moves or the advent of a “currency war.” Credit is due to the Chinese government, which has held fire so far. But, amid softening domestic demand (the Chinese government this week lowered its growth target to 7 percent, despite substantial stimulus), any move by China to moderate the pace of renminbi appreciation against the dollar or other currencies as a response to the yen’s move would likely trigger a chain reaction in the region. Europe also will be watching the yen’s move closely. Although there are good reasons close to home for the European Central Bank to ease monetary policy, on the margin the Japanese move contributes to deflationary pressures in Europe. The United States is in a different position. Trade is a relatively small share of its economy, and so even a material appreciation is unlikely to undermine the strong growth outlook and continued strengthening of the labor market. So why worry? Indeed, U.S. policymakers appear broadly supportive of Japanese monetary policy, and see stronger growth in Japan, however achieved, as a positive contribution to the global outlook. The problem is as much political as economic. A sharp appreciation of the U.S. dollar against its major trading partners, driven by expectations that the Federal Reserve will begin to normalize policy while others ease, is bound to be contentious. There could be particular ramifications for trade. Congress is likely to produce a bill granting the president trade promotion authority (TPA), which is essential for any meaningful agreements on TPP or other trade negotiations underway. This case for bipartisanship on this issue is based on the historical Republican support for free trade, and recognition that Democrats have been the primary hurdle to passage of free trade agreements to date. Perhaps optimism is justified, but do not underestimate the risk that negotiations could go off track. In the past, both parties have pressed for tough language requiring any trade deal to address exchange-rate misalignments, and that pressure is likely to mount if dollar strength is seen as a risk for the economy. Such exchange-rate language could be a dealbreaker, as it is hard to see Japan or other U.S. trading partners making the tough concessions needed to agree to these conditions. There is much to commend the Bank of Japan for as it reverses decades of orthodox policy in order to jump-start growth with aggressive monetary easing. But relying on only one arrow presents both economic and political risks at home and abroad. Let us hope that optimism about the structural arrow proves correct. Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon Draghi needs to start acting European Central Bank (ECB) President Mario Draghi has been promising to do whatever it takes to restore growth and achieve price stability, and needs to deliver now, beginning with the ECB’s December meeting. Greek elections loom Snap elections highlight Greece’s continuing economic challenges and could reinvigorate a debate over the adequacy of Europe’s crisis response. Cheap oil burns holes in government budgets Falling oil prices are putting significant pressure on a number of exporters’ government finances, including Russia, Venezuela, and Nigeria.
  • Europe and Eurasia
    Bank Valuations Tank as ECB Flubs Its Stress Test
    Low market valuations (i.e., price to book ratios) for euro area banks reflect market concerns over their capital cushions, opined the Bank of England just prior to last-year’s launch of the ECB stress tests—the long-awaited results of which were published on October 26.  The tests, “by improving transparency,” said the BoE, have “the potential to improve confidence in euro area banks.” So did they? We looked at market valuations just before and after publication of the test results.  As can be seen from the right-hand figure above, they rose sharply, both in absolute terms and relative to the broader market, in the week leading up to publication—a period in which there was considerable speculation that the results would be good.  They were indeed good, with only 25 out of 130 banks failing, but valuations plummeted over the three weeks following publication, in absolute terms and relative to the broader market.  28 of the 31 Euro Stoxx index banks tested now trade at lower valuations than they did before the results were released. Over that three-week period, independent analyses were steadily coming out—among them, ours—criticizing the tests for flaws such as inflated inflation assumptions and over-generous treatment of deferred tax assets as capital.  The ECB’s conclusion that the banks needed to raise a mere €9.5 billion in additional capital was thus not credible, and indeed fell way short of what independent analysts were suggesting. In sum, the ECB has indeed improved transparency, revealing through data publication just how weak the capital base of the euro area banking sector actually is.  But in its unwillingness to call a spade a spade and to do something about it, it has failed to “improve confidence in euro area banks,” as the BoE had hoped it would.  The reason may lie in the fact that public-sector funds are needed but may not necessarily be made available by those that have them—a problem we flagged back in March. The ECB’s failed stress tests thus enter into the euro area’s already crowded stress test Hall of Shame.   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Budget, Debt, and Deficits
    Japan’s Sensible Fiscal Retreat
    Surprisingly poor second quarter growth numbers in Japan have raised market expectations that there will be snap elections and a delay in the consumption tax hike that was scheduled for October 2015. GDP fell for a second consecutive quarter, by 1.6 percent (q/q, a.r), versus market expectations of a 2.2 percent increase. A huge miss. Falling corporate inventories were a large part of the story, but exports rose only modestly while household consumption and capital spending slowed. The yen sold off after the announcement, reaching a low of 117 against the dollar. Japanese stocks are higher. Most G-20 policymakers, concerned about global growth, will salute the move by the Japanese government to avoid a fiscal contraction. David Cameron, notably, saying that “red warning lights are flashing on the dashboard of the global economy”, captured the sour mood of this past weekend’s Brisbane Summit. More directly, U.S. Treasury Secretary Lew, in his speech ahead of the G-20 summit, called on Japan to pay “attention to short-term growth alongside medium-term fiscal objectives. To maintain the recovery and escape deflation, Japan needs to move proactively and decisively to more than fully offset the short-term contractionary impact of the expiration of past fiscal measures and the next consumption tax increase, should Prime Minister Abe decide to proceed with it on the current schedule. The most effective policy would give households short term relief to encourage consumption. A few years ago, in the United States, we implemented a temporary payroll tax holiday to accomplish a similar goal.” He went on to call for a renewed a structural reform effort, the “third arrow” of Abenomics, on which there has been little progress. Other G-20 leaders made similar remarks.  Larry Summers and Paul Krugman reinforced this call for a delay in the tax hike (Paul wouldn’t mind a permanent shift), with the IMF on the other side (though they may soften their view following release of these numbers).  Overall, policymakers are right to be concerned about growth, and in this context, Japan is doing the right thing. The G-20’s cautious endorsement of the delay in the consumption tax hike doesn’t mean that Japanese policy isn’t causing problems for global policy coordination following the recent aggressive monetary easing by the Bank of Japan (BOJ). I have previously endorsed the BOJ’s actions, doubling down on monetary policy, even in the absence of substantial success on the other two arrows of Abenomics. But that means, as far as support for recovery goes—it’s all about the money. A primary channel through which easier money will drive demand is through a significant and continuing depreciation of the yen. The market’s Abenomics (weak yen) trade lives on. One issue that has not received much attention is that, at the same time the BOJ announced its easing of policy, the government pension investment fund (GPIF) announced a shift in its portfolio away from domestic bonds and into domestic and foreign stocks. Combining monetary easing with direct purchases of foreign stocks is the economic equivalent of direct exchange rate intervention, something the G-20 has previously ruled out. Particularly if the Japanese moves bring forth copycat depreciations elsewhere, this will be a continuing issue for discussion in the coming months, and could find its way to Capitol Hill in the context of upcoming debates over trade policy.
  • Monetary Policy
    Paul Krugman Calls for "Weak-Dollar Policy"...Towards Mars?
    Paul Krugman routinely mocks Germany for wanting “everyone to run enormous trade surpluses at the same time.” As Martin Wolf has put it, this is impossible, as “the world cannot trade with Mars.” What we find amazing is that Krugman does not see a similar problem with his latest call for the United States to run “a weak-dollar policy.” Against whom should the U.S. pursue a weak dollar? As today’s Geo-Graphic shows, major economies outside the U.S. are in no condition to support stronger currencies.  Of the G-7 economies, as the main figure above indicates, only the U.S. and Canada – which have the second- and third-highest growth rates – have inflation near the developed-market standard of 2%.  The others, save the UK, have much lower growth and inflation.  The U.S. pursuing a weak-dollar policy towards its G-7 partners, therefore, would appear deeply damaging and misguided. The G-7 represents nearly half the global economy.  As for emerging markets, the small inset graph shows stagnant growth rates after years of decline.  Against this background, it looks difficult to justify a generalized appreciation of EM currencies. In short, we suspect that Krugman’s call for a weak-dollar policy can only mean one thing: currency war with Mars. CNBC: Why Currency Wars Could Stave Off a Fed Rate Hike Wall Street Journal: Fed Minutes Show Wariness Over Global Growth Financial Times: U.S. Dollar Surges After Strong Data WSJ's Real Time Economics: The Return of the Currency Wars   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Budget, Debt, and Deficits
    Global Economics Monthly: November 2014
    Bottom Line: The European Central Bank's (ECB) recent asset-quality review (AQR) and stress test of eurozone banks was an important step. But restarting growth requires stronger macro policies if Europe is to avoid a Japan-style lost decade. That includes a more concerted effort to deal with the sovereign debt overhang that is a threat to consumption, investment, and growth. In my recent Policy Innovation Memorandum (PIM), I argue that the overhang of debt is a critical constraint on growth, and call for debt relief for Europe's periphery. Why now? Partly, I expect debt issues will return to the fore over the coming years as growth stalls, adjustment fatigue increases, and spreads on periphery sovereign debt rise again. In addition, many of the critical policy debates in Europe were sidelined while awaiting the ECB-led AQR and stress test of the major European banks, which was released at the end of October. Supporters hoped that a credible stress test, and the positive market reaction that resulted, would represent a turning point in the crisis and "jump-start" the European economy. "I definitely think the banking crisis is behind us," said Dutch Finance Minister and Eurogroup President Jeroen Dijsselbloem after the release of the report. Such optimism is misguided and dangerous. The AQR and stress test constitute a serious effort to address the capital shortfall and restore confidence in the financial system, but they do not address all concerns. The review sets the stage for the ECB to emerge as the single supervisor and regulator for Europe's major banks, an important—if incomplete—step toward banking union. This effort, however, will not jump-start lending or get Europe growing again. Without growth, how confident can we really be that the crisis is over? Absent more supportive policies, the banking sector cannot regain its health, capital will remain inadequate, and a year from now the stress test may well look unconvincing. In that regard, I agree with Gavyn Davies: the exercise is a "necessary, but far from sufficient, step to fix the low-growth, low-inflation condition that has become the norm in the European economy." Europe's Three Arrows: The Japanification of Europe Concerns about European growth are a growing weight on markets. At the recent International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank annual meetings, there was widespread talk of the risk of "Japanification" of the European economy, meaning a prolonged period of underperforming growth and low inflation. Though there was no consensus, I came away convinced that Europe needs its own version of Japan's Abenomics—its own "three arrows": Monetary policy. ECB sources have been quoted as suggesting that bolder action, including the purchase of government bonds (quantitative easing, or QE), could come before the end of 2014 or at the January 2015 meeting. A narrow majority (Germany is not alone in its opposition) now seems to recognize that current policies are inadequate, but it appears unlikely that the ECB will be proactive or clearly articulate its commitment to QE unless growth and inflation numbers get significantly worse. Forward guidance on policy, as much as the purchases themselves, will provide the real boost in the European case. Fiscal policy. Europe needs a more countercyclical fiscal policy, with greater spending by the surplus countries providing the demand that is missing as the periphery countries continue to consolidate, but it is hard to imagine such coordination on fiscal policy any time soon. The IMF expects European fiscal policy to be broadly neutral in 2015–2016. Structural policies. Although Spain is credited with some significant reforms, the regional reform agenda—including labor-market, spending, and product-market reforms—lags elsewhere in Europe. A comprehensive supply-side reform is needed to raise potential growth, though it should be acknowledged that structural reform often is disruptive politically and economically in the short run. There are two problems here. First, these remedies are well understood by European leaders—the problem is not imagination, but leadership. Europe remains stuck, and it seems that only a crisis can spur the needed response. Second, the downside of the analogy to Japan and the three arrows of Abenomics is that Europe should also address a fourth arrow—the debt overhang—which exerts a continuing drag on investment and confidence. With the stress test complete, now is the time to address this problem as part of a comprehensive pro-growth package. Debt Policy: The Missing Fourth Arrow Across Europe, sovereign debt is higher than it was immediately following the financial crisis. Last year, gross government debt was 175 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) in Greece and 133 percent in Italy; Portugal and Ireland's governments both hold debt stocks over 120 percent of GDP. Meanwhile, household and corporate debt remains high and continues to threaten bank balance sheets. Low interest rates make these debt burdens manageable for now, and have allowed countries such as Greece and Portugal to reenter markets. But with growth through 2015 projected at an anemic 1 percent, this is a problem deferred, not solved. Continued uncertainty over debt will condemn Europe to years of low growth and its attendant ills. Growth projections for the short- and medium-term are far too low to relieve problems like extreme unemployment—in excess of 35 percent for youths in Spain, Greece, Portugal, and Italy—and the social and political instability it can ignite. Continued weak economic performance will only further reduce confidence and investment, possibly widening the premium on periphery sovereign debt. The way out of the growth doldrums resides in forcefully tackling the debt problem. Europe's leaders need to find the political will to launch a structured debt-relief program. In my PIM, I argue that one place to begin is by looking to the Paris Club, an informal group of official creditors that convenes to address debt problems in low- and middle-income countries. Though my European friends hate my analogy to a forum that supports developing countries, clear lessons can be drawn. Specifically, Europe should implement four of the Paris Club's principles. First, rules should be adopted on a case-by-case basis to tailor restructuring programs to a country's income and debt level. Second, predictable debt relief should be conditional on policy performance, including structural reforms, continued progress toward fiscal balance, and programs to address the burden of corporate-sector debt. Third, countries should receive a cutoff date that would delimit the debt eligible for restructuring. In all cases, only debt accrued before that date would be eligible. This makes the country receiving relief fully responsible for any future debt accumulated. Finally, comparability of treatment for other creditors should not be ruled out as needed. The Paris Club framework is particularly important in the case of Europe, where much of the debt is owed to creditors in the official sector. This is particularly true in the case of Greece. At the end of last year, Greece had received a total of nearly 215 billion euros from "the Troika"—a group made up of the European Commission, the ECB (through the European Financial Stability Facility, or EFSF), and the IMF. This amount was equivalent to 108 percent of Greece's 2013 GDP and 62 percent of its total debt stock (see Figure 1). As a result of the 2012 private restructuring, the vast majority of Greece's debt is now owed to official creditors. Resolving disputes among these official creditors will be much easier if a set of rules is in place. In addition, consideration could be given to reducing debt held by the European Central Bank as part of rescue efforts. Citigroup Chief Economist Willem Buiter has an innovative proposal to cancel ECB debt holdings purchased to fund a temporary fiscal stimulus package. The principle also applies to the bonds the ECB has acquired as part of rescue efforts in the periphery. Figure 1: Greece's Troika and Non-Troika Debt, Year-End 2013 Source: European Commission Criticisms of proposals like these often start with a call for realism. It is highly unlikely that Germany and the other creditor countries would agree to commit to debt relief, even if highly conditional on policy reform, because such a commitment would make explicit the costs of sustaining the European Monetary Union with an incomplete set of economic policies. These creditors are concerned by the precedent a major debt-relief effort might set and by the issue of moral hazard (i.e., that easy relief would encourage recipient countries to relax their reform efforts and return to their bad old ways). But making explicit the cost of saving the eurozone with all its current members is simply good governance, as compared to hiding the costs by presuming they will be repaid in full. Further, the moral hazard problem, though a real concern, can be addressed by making relief conditional on performance. Finally, over the longer term, Germany does not benefit from killing its export markets in the periphery. These factors together make a compelling case for a structured program of debt relief. A Lost Decade Now is the time to embark on a comprehensive effort to restart growth in Europe, including a fourth arrow aimed at debt reduction. Low interest rates, the relief provided by earlier maturity extensions, and the confidence that could be achieved from the stress test combine to create a window for action on the debt. A year from now, if growth has not returned, indebted governments will be called on to rescue or shore up weak banks, uncertainty will return, and confidence and investment will be much harder to achieve. Europe needs a rules-based approach to debt relief. The Paris Club is one place to look for guidance to begin setting these rules. The sooner they are established, the sooner Europe will see a return to growth. Otherwise, a lost decade looms. Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon Lame Outlook for the Lame Duck The U.S. Congress faces a long to-do list for the lame-duck session but is likely to achieve little; the international agenda—e.g., IMF reform and trade promotion authority— is likely to be deferred. More Economic Woes for Ukraine and Russia In Ukraine, the IMF team heads out. A large financing gap looms, calling the IMF program into question. Meanwhile, the Russian economy slips into recession. A Global Slowdown October saw analysts marking down their global growth forecasts, a trend likely to continue in November.
  • Europe and Eurasia
    The ECB Fails to Stress Banks Over the One Critical Variable It Controls: Inflation
    Relentlessly falling inflation is bad news for Eurozone banks.  It increases the real (inflation-adjusted) value of borrower debt and the real cost of servicing that debt.  It causes loan defaults, and therefore bank loan losses, to rise. So with Eurozone inflation, currently at a near-record low of 0.4%, clearly at risk of heading into deflationary territory, what did the ECB say was the “adverse scenario” for this year?  Inflation of 1% – more than twice its current level.  This is indefensible; the ECB’s dire scenario for this year is actually much cheerier than the IMF’s baseline forecast, which pegs inflation at 0.5%.  The country-by-country comparison is shown in the graphic above. Disturbingly, at no point through the end of 2016 is the ECB even willing to contemplate the possibility of inflation being less than it already was in September: 0.3%.  This is a serious failure on the part of the central bank, which this month assumes supervisory responsibility for Eurozone banks.  It suggests that the ECB is more concerned with the reputational costs of acknowledging the possibility of deflation than with testing accurately the ability of banks to withstand it.  As the private sector is not privy to the proprietary bank data that would allow such a proper test, the ECB’s failure to address deflation risks raises the critical unanswerable question of how many of the seven banks that barely passed should actually have failed. Buiter: Four Rescue Measures for Stagnant Eurozone Evans-Pritchard: ECB Stress Tests Vastly Understate Risk of Deflation and Leverage Legrain: Yet Another Eurozone Bank Whitewash Financial Times: Bank Stress Tests Fail to Tackle Deflation Spectre Steil and Walker: Restoring Financial Stability in the Eurozone   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Europe
    Three Central Banks
    Today’s central bank news tells us a lot about the risks and rewards of proactive central banking. The Bank of Japan (BoJ) surprised me (and nearly everyone else ) with a dramatic expansion of its unconventional monetary policy this morning, citing renewed risks of deflation. The BOJ announced (i) an increase in the target for monetary base growth to ¥80 trillion ($730 billion) per annum from ¥60–70 trillion; (2) an increase in its Japanese government bond (JGB) purchases to an annual pace of ¥80 trillion from ¥50 trillion; (3) an extension of the average maturity of its JGB purchases to 7–10 years (3 years previously); and (4) a tripling of its targets for the annual purchases of Japan real estate investment trusts (J-REITs) and exchange-traded funds (ETFs). In addition, and more controversially, the Japanese Government Pension Investment Fund (GPIF) will shift its portfolio away from government bonds and towards equities, both domestic and foreign, doubling the share of equities to 50 percent. As a general rule it’s not such a good idea to use government wealth funds as an instrument of monetary policy in this way, but given that government policy in the past has been so heavily tilted towards support of the bond market, it can be argued that this is a good move from a longer-run perspective, and it does arguably strengthen the near-term wealth effects of quantitative easing. It is also worth noting that the BoJ has followed the lead of other central banks and moved away from date-based guidance (achieving 2 percent inflation within two years of the start of the program, a target that was always optimistic and now quickly slipping out of reach) to a focus on balance sheet targets. That makes sense. There was a fair degree of attention paid to the fact that the vote was 5-4 for easing. For most central banks, such a closely divided vote would be a negative. Here, however, I see decisiveness. As long as we assume BoJ Governor Haruhiko Kuroda can command a majority on critical decisions, which I do, his willingness to move proactively as soon as a majority exists shows strength. There is some speculation in the markets that the BoJ move was given a green light when the U.S. Treasury did not mention yen weakness as a concern in its recent exchange rate report. I think this is oversold as an explanation. What I do see at play is a central bank that--while motivated by domestic considerations--is taking advantage of the Fed’s turn toward normalization to make a dramatic move that, by emphasizing the divergence of policy, ensures a substantial market impact. Today the yen reached a six-year low against the dollar at 112.4 and stocks rose sharply. That said, I would not be surprised to see exchange rate tensions intensify in coming months and feature centrally in upcoming G-7 and G-20 debates. The BoJ’s move could put additional pressure of the European Central Bank (ECB) to act when it meets next week, though few analysts expect a move to purchase government bonds (sovereign QE) until December at the earliest and more likely next year. There may well be a narrow majority for such a move, but in contrast to the BOJ, failure to act (combined with muddy messaging) ensures that monetary policy will continue to provide weak support for the recovery. Europe needs its own “three arrows”, as well as more aggressive action to deal with the crushing debt overhang. Finally, the Central Bank of Russia surprised markets with a 150 bp increase in interest rates, raising the benchmark rate to 9.5 percent from 5.5 percent at the start of the tightening cycle. With inflation at 8.4 percent and rising (against a target of 5.5 percent), and food inflation several points higher, the central bank was pressured to act. However, the currency sold off following the announcement, despite announcement of an oil agreement with Ukraine, reading the move as a sign of a sharply weakening economy and recognition of the limited commitment of the central bank to defend the currency. I think that is right. The economy is headed for a deep recession, capital flight is continuing, and sanctions are more likely to be intensified than eased in coming months.  In sum, it’s hard not to expect that capital controls will soon follow.
  • Monetary Policy
    Our Fed Dual-Mandate Tracker Affirms Taper Timing
    St. Louis Fed President James Bullard continues to burnish his reputation as the FOMC’s least predictable member, reversing course on policy for the second time in 3 months—going from dove to hawk and now back to dove again.  Having as recently as August publicly advocated a rate rise in early 2015, he is now calling for the Fed to halt its monthly taper of QE3 bond purchases, citing falling inflation expectations. But the Fed’s own preferred measure of inflation expectations, the 5-year 5-year forward breakeven inflation rate, has barely moved since the FOMC’s September meeting—down from 2.4% to 2.3%.  Furthermore, as the figure above shows, if we benchmark the Fed’s performance against its dual mandate of price stability and maximum employment, using the Fed’s own definition of each, we see that it has, since the start of the taper in January, been steadily on track towards the zero bliss point. Bullard has always defended his policy calls as data-driven, but in this case he seems to be navigating more by gut calls as to where the data may be moving in the future.  Our dual-mandate tracker suggests clearly that the Fed should stay the course on taper. Calculated Risk: FOMC Preview Financial Times: U.S. Federal Reserve Set to Halt Asset Purchases Bloomberg News: Treasuries Rise on Speculation Fed May Keep Low-Rate Policy Wall Street Journal: Fedspeak Cheatsheet   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Russia
    Global Economics Monthly: October 2014
    Bottom Line: The use of financial and economic sanctions against Russia demonstrates their power to penalize countries with globally integrated markets. We now need a strategy for convincing other countries (and markets) that this new weapon will be reserved for combating serious violations of international norms and not used as leverage in conventional commercial disputes. A code of best practice or principles could help guide the use of sanctions. In debating the consequences of Western sanctions on Russia,some observers voice concerns that sanctions are becoming an easy option for the United States and its allies when conflicts emerge. In a war-weary world, sanctions are an attractive alternative to military action, and, as I have argued elsewhere, the Russia experience has demonstrated the power of financial sanctions to impose costs on large, globally integrated economies. By imposing sanctions, Western powers wanted to send a strong signal to Russia (and to other countries contemplating similar actions) that there was a price to be paid for its violation of Ukrainian sovereignty and continued destabilization of the region. The United States and Europe may also have wanted to send a broader message: governments should adhere to basic international norms if they wish to participate in global markets. But concerns have now risen regarding which norms will be defended and how. What constitutes an egregious violation of international rules? I have been an advocate of comprehensive sanctions in order to impose substantial up-front costs on Russia. I have also argued that there is inevitable momentum for an extension of sanctions in this case, both as a response to Russia's actions in Ukraine and to its evasion of sanctions announced earlier. I still see this expansion as appropriate, although I recognize the costs to U.S. and European interests. However, it is also important that sanctions advocates address the risks of extension, including the concern that certain measures to increase sanctions could disrupt global markets to a greater extent than previously witnessed. Already there are reports of market makers pulling back on risk positions over concerns of a broader lack of liquidity should sanctions be extended to current payments. Such concerns can act as a brake on international cooperation and encourage countries to limit their integration in global markets as an insurance policy against future sanctions. More broadly, such considerations may increase efforts to create new international institutions, such as the Asian Investment Infrastructure Bank (AIIB), which risk fragmenting the framework for global economic governance if not properly coordinated with existing international financial institutions, such as the World Bank and Asian Development Bank. These concerns about the future overuse of financial sanctions fall into three basic categories: Are financial sanctions too easy to implement? Sanctions could become an easy option that is too readily applied in future cases. Although sanctions have not brought about peace in Ukraine, I would argue that the effects on Russia are significant and the costs will rise over time as capital outflows continue, investment in Russia is discouraged, and lost confidence contributes to a low-growth, high-inflation outcome for the Russian economy. Historically, it was assumed that a strong international consensus was needed for sanctions to be effective. That may be less true now; the power of sanctions stems from a country's exclusion from financial markets, providing some scope for the United States to go it alone. Is the United States at risk? Other countries may find their inhibitions lowered on the use of sanctions, making the United States a possible future target. One could imagine that, for example, countries opposed to U.S. policy on Taiwan or the Middle East might impose sanctions citing the Russian example. How far is too far? Once sanctions have been imposed, the pressure to extend them could lead to excessive use. In the Russian context, this debate revolves around whether sanctions should be imposed on the payments system. To some, the payments system is a global public good that needs to be protected, which suggests that a higher standard should be set for sanctions in this area. Unlike a prohibition on oil drilling by foreign companies, for example, a restriction on Russia's access to the payments systems reduces the benefits to other users across the globe. The Policy Response The United States and its allies no doubt value their options in the current environment. Indeed, the ambiguity about what could come next creates an additional cost for those considering doing business in Russia, which constitutes an important element of the effectiveness of sanctions. But that same ambiguity is a source of concern and can contribute to a loss of legitimacy. Can this leverage be preserved while assuring the rest of the world that sanctions will be used judiciously and appropriately? The strategy for addressing these concerns may have relied on other governance reforms, such as International Monetary Fund (IMF) quota reform and market-strengthening initiatives—including a Doha Round agreement, the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP), and the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP)—to signal U.S. commitment to an open, thriving, and rules-based global marketplace. Unfortunately, all these initiatives appear to be in trouble, as does the global trade liberalization agenda more broadly. Better communication can also be part of the strategy. It was inevitable, given the complexity of the standoff in Ukraine and the need to build alliances with the Europeans, that policy would have to evolve in ways that were not always transparent to markets. Now that the United States and its European allies have more experience, there is an opportunity to distill lessons and explain the policy both to other countries and to the broader public. A conversation with allies about the principles behind sanctions comes at a useful time. Some European countries are experiencing fraying support for sanctions, perhaps associated with differential costs from the sanctions and concerns about an energy shortage if the dispute extends into winter. With sanctions at current levels, these tensions can be mitigated, but opposition could intensify should the U.S. government decide to extend sanctions. A more ambitious idea would be to explore the possibility of a global code of conduct, or rules of engagement, which specifies—in a more concrete fashion than has been done to date—the conditions that could lead to the imposition of sanctions by the United States and its allies. There are other examples of informal codes in the economic sphere that can provide inspiration. The Santiago Principles, for example, are a set of twenty-four voluntary guidelines for investments by sovereign wealth funds that were agreed to by a broad range of countries in 2008—both those with sovereign wealth funds and those receiving investments. The analogy is not direct, as the Santiago Principles focused on ensuring that states acted in a commercial manner and avoided destructive competition through commitments regarding disclosure, transparency, regulation, and governance. Nevertheless, there are some interesting parallels. First, the codes were voluntary and designed to respect the sovereignty and independence of the state-owned investment funds and the need to maintain control over investment choices. Second, the goal was to encourage better international standards and establish best practices to promote accountability and transparency. These principles have been successful in framing the investor behavior of these funds and also in clearing away some of the uncertainty and ambiguity surrounding these organizations. Any code of conduct would need to promote transparency regarding the decision to impose sanctions and their application, objectives, and conditions for removal. This code would discourage retaliatory measures and tit-for-tat responses that could prove destructive. It may be a bridge too far to seek agreement on a specific code. But even in this case, the effort to articulate goals and objectives could help stabilize markets and address the concerns of important U.S. allies. Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon Infrastructure Matters The IMF and World Bank meetings called for more and better infrastructure spending, but can the Group of Twenty (G20) agree on meaningful initiatives ahead of November's Brisbane Summit? Exchange Rates in Focus Market commentary increasingly highlights divergent Group of Three (G3) monetary policy as a source of exchange-rate and broader-market volatility. Ukraine Elections Should we expect a populist backlash against austerity? With the IMF program failing, the new parliament that is elected on October 26 will have some tough decisions on the economy.
  • Monetary Policy
    Are Fed Doves Mucking with Future Unemployment Estimates to Justify Dovishness?
    Do Fed doves and hawks get their aviary classifications based on their cold, hard analysis of data, or is it the reverse – do they select data points to justify their dovish or hawkish perspectives? The history of the Fed’s post-crisis focus on unemployment suggests the latter.  After June of 2013, as the figure above shows, the Fed’s estimate of the natural long-term unemployment rate begins declining in sync with the decline in the actual unemployment rate.  This suggests that FOMC members are lowering their estimates of the natural rate of unemployment to justify keeping interest rates at zero longer than they could if they stuck by their initial estimates, the 6% consensus upper bound of which is now above today’s actual 5.9% rate. We cannot test this hypothesis directly, by checking each member’s estimate history, because the estimates are anonymous.  But we can check whether the phenomenon can be explained merely by a change of FOMC composition: it cannot. The distribution of participants’ estimates shows conclusively that some of them have indeed revised their estimates lower.  Given that these are supposed to be estimates of the "long-term" natural unemployment rate, this is more than curious. With core PCE inflation, the Fed’s preferred inflation measure, running at 1.5%, still comfortably below the Fed’s 2% long-run target, there is little compelling reason to begin hiking rates immediately.  But given its upward trajectory from 1.2% at the start of the year, there is surely now reasoned cause for bringing forward the Fed’s old September 2012 calendar-guidance of zero rates through mid-2015 – which the Fed doves are still strongly wedded to. Our observations suggest that monetary dovishness and hawkishness are often fixed states of mind, rather than artifacts of a consistent approach to data analysis.  If so, there is reason to fear that the Fed’s exit from monetary accommodation will be too late and too tepid – with the result being higher future inflation than the market is pricing in right now. Financial Times: Jobs Data Show United States Beating Global Economy Wall Street Journal: Falling Unemployment Alone Not Reason To Raise Rates, Fed’s Kocherlakota Says Yellen: Perspectives on Monetary Policy Orphanides and Williams: Monetary Policy Mistakes and the Evolution of Inflation Expectations   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • China
    Can Russia Escape Dollar Dependence?
    Russian president Vladimir Putin is determined to wean his country off the dollar, or so he says. In July, after insisting that the international monetary system depended too much “on the U.S. dollar, or, to be precise, on the monetary and financial policy of the U.S. authorities,” Putin signed off on a new BRICS development bank whose initial paid-in capital would be entirely in dollars – unlike the World Bank, where only 10% of paid-in capital was in dollars.  So the new BRICS bank actually creates a new source of demand for dollar assets. Now, he wants to diversify Russia’s holdings in its two sovereign wealth funds (SWF), the Reserve Fund and National Wealth Fund, away from dollars – and euros as well.  Finance minister Anton Siluanov has announced that funds will soon be directed into financial assets issued by its fellow BRICS nations – Brazil, India, China, and South Africa. There are some caveats, however.  Siluanov suggested that the shift would be mainly into “Eurobonds issued under English law,” which effectively means dollar- and euro-denominated bonds.  As the figure above shows, however, total international bond issuance by Brazil, India, China, and South Africa amounts to only $45 billion, or a mere 26% of the holdings of Russia’s SWFs.  Furthermore, Russia’s two funds are currently restricted to investments in securities rated AA- or better by Fitch, or Aa3 or better by Moody’s.  Only China’s international bonds meet these criteria, which would leave Russia with a potential pool of investable assets worth a mere $1.5 billion – less than 1% of Russia’s SWF assets. Russia could, of course, relax the constraint that the bonds be issued internationally, in hard currency, and invest in local currency bonds.  Brazil, for example, which Siluanov singled out as an investment destination, has issued about $800 billion worth of local-currency bonds.  But the Brazilian Real has depreciated by 10% against the dollar in the past month alone, and “capital preservation” is a fundamental investment objective of Russia’s SWFs.  With Russian capital flight approaching dangerous levels (Fitch projects $120 billion for this year), and rumors flying that capital controls will be imposed to staunch the outflow, would Russia really be willing to bet its solvency on the Real in order to make a political point of little or no consequence for the dollar’s global reserve status? Not a chance. Ministry of Finance of the Russian Federation: National Wealth Fund Wall Street Journal: Did Russia Just Move Its Treasury Holdings Offshore? TesouroNacional: Brazil Federal Public Debt Annual Borrowing Plan 2014 Bank of Russia: International Reserves of the Russian Federation   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Monetary Policy
    A Dovish Market Has History on Its Side in Tuning Out the Fed
    Market expectations for Fed policy have been decidedly more dovish than the Fed itself, a conundrum that is concerning San Francisco Fed economists.  As the Fed debates its rate-liftoff forward guidance this week, however, it is worth asking how much it really matters. We have long argued that the market has been perfectly rational in tuning out elements of central-bank forward guidance that aren’t credible.  Today’s Geo-Graphic shows why the market may well have it right again. As the figure above shows, going back to 1992 the Fed has never raised rates less than 225 days after the end of a policy-easing cycle.  In 1992, the gap was 518 days.  In 1996 and 2003 the gap was also over a year. So with QE3 set to wind down in October, the market has history on its side in expecting a later transition to tightening (beginning this time next year), and a slower one, than Fed forecasts and statements suggest. Reuters: Fed to Drop “Considerable Time” Next Week, Top Economist Says Wall Street Journal: Can the Fed Drop “Considerable Time” Without Spooking Markets? Financial Times: Fed Should Raise Rates Sooner Than Later Yellen: Perspectives on Monetary Policy   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Europe
    The Geopolitical Paradox: Dangerous World, Resilient Markets
    Should we be worried by how well global markets are performing despite rising geopolitical volatility? I think so. In my September monthly, I look at the main arguments explaining the disconnect, and argue Europe is the region we should be most worried about a disruptive correction. Here are a few excerpts. • Far Away and Uncorrelated. Much of the market commentary has stressed that the risks that most worry political analysts—for example Russia, ISIL and Syria, Syria, an Ebola pandemic—are not necessarily central to global growth and market prospects. But small (in GDP terms)and far away does not mean inconsequential. As the debate over financial sanctions has shown, its Russia’s leverage and interconnectedness, rather than its global trade share, that makes comprehensive sanctions so powerful and potentially disruptive. • A Sea of Global Liquidity. There is little doubt that the highly accommodative monetary policies of the United States, eurozone, United Kingdom, and Japan have provided an important firewall against geopolitical risk. Looking ahead, global liquidity will remain ample, but with the U.S. and U.K. beginning to normalize, and the BOJ and ECB going in the other direction, the divergence of monetary policies creates conditions for increased market volatility. Foreign exchange markets in particular appear vulnerable, as history suggests these markets are often bellwethers of divergent monetary policies. • Confident Oil Markets. A stable and moderate global expansion that has limited demand, as well as the revolution in fracking and other technologies, has allowed Saudi Arabia to maintain substantial spare capacity, thereby limiting the potential for a supply disruption to roil markets in the near term (though the longer-term buffering effects on market prices from these developments can be overestimated). But it is hard to imagine that broad based turmoil in the middle east, and the possible rewriting of borders, can be achieved without a material disruption to supplies at some point. • Europe as the Weak Link. I see Europe as the channel through which political risk could reverberate in the global economy. The standoff with Russia, or a hard landing in China could significantly affect exports, particularly in Germany. Significantly, though, Europe also faces these challenges at a time of economic stress and limited resilience. Growth in the region has disappointed and leading indicators have tilted downward. Further, concern about deflation is beginning to weigh on sentiment and investment. The persistence of low inflation is symptomatic of deeper structural problems facing the eurozone, including an incomplete monetary union, deep-seated competitiveness problems in the periphery, and devastatingly high unemployment. Homegrown political risks also threaten to add to the turmoil, as rising discontent within Europe over the costs of austerity is undermining governing parties and fueling populism. The result is a monetary union with little capacity or resilience to defend against shocks. The ECB has responded to these risks with interest-rate cuts and asset purchases, and is expected to move to quantitative easing later this year or early next, but the move comes late, and is unlikely to do more than address the headwinds associated with the ongoing banking reform and continued fiscal austerity. Overall, a return to crisis is an increasing concern and political risks could be the trigger that we should be worried about.
  • Sub-Saharan Africa
    Africa, The Summit and Development
    This is a guest post by Owen Cylke. Mr. Cylke is a development professional and a retired senior foreign service officer with U.S. Agency for International Development. References to development (even to the word “development”) do not appear in most of the reports on the recently concluded U.S.-Africa Leaders Summit. In this regard, I want to distinguish between “assistance” and “development,” between discrete projects on the one hand, and, on the other, the larger, more complex process of transforming economies, polities, administrations, and societies. Yet, the advancement of development is a stated goal of the president of the United States, the U.S. Agency for International Development, the Millennium Challenge Corporation, the World Bank, the International Finance Corporation, and the International Monetary Fund. Development also has the focused attention of African leadership as reflected in the policies and actions of the African Union, its development arm the New Partnership for Africa’s Development (NEPAD), the Africa Development Bank (AfDB) and the constitutions, policies, and actions of virtually every country on the continent. What might account for this counter-intuitive neglect to the idea of development? The argument that Africa is in a post-assistance position based on rapid growth in a dozen country’s might explain in part the step away from development as an organizing principle of the summit; yet, there is the recently proposed bailout for Ghana, up to now the poster country for the post-assistance argument. It could also be partly attributable to the ongoing assault on the role of government in both U.S. domestic and international policies and politics. This is in contrast with the resurrection of state action in support of development seen across the continent. Another possibility could be the focus on the growth of private sector investment (which can, or cannot, be supportive of broad-based, equitable, inclusive, and sustainable development). Or, it could be the increased concern about security issues in central and west Africa, giving rise to the increasing presence and prominence of the defense agencies in discussions about Africa (again without reference to the strong linkages between development and insecurity). Nevertheless, all in all, it is curious that development writ large–as an idea and ambition-was curiously missing (or short-changed) in discussion at the U.S. Africa Leaders Summit. Of course, it will be argued that a whole range of government development initiatives was on the agenda, even if development as an organizing idea and ambition was not. But Africa’s challenge is not about assistance and projects. It is rather about development that needs to happen, broadly, equitably, and sustainably. Development needs to happen in the Democratic Republic of the Congo, Liberia, Zimbabwe, Burundi, Eritrea, the Central African Republic, Niger, Sierra Leone, Malawi, and Togo, and it needs to continue to happen in Nigeria and South Africa. Had development as such been on the agenda, what might a report from the Summit have looked like? That is anyone’s guess, but my own line of inquiry might have included the following: • how to re-energize the development discourse, with particular emphasis on the transformation of productive capabilities and structure; • what approaches would encourage greater attention to industrial/urban and technology/innovation policies and strategies; • how to encourage greater respect for the approach and thinking of development institutions and strategies across Africa as they coalesce around new practices and theories of development; • what are the implications of globalization and liberalization; • how best to promote local and national development through the institutional and productive transformation of regions.