Economics

Monetary Policy

  • China
    Move Over Big Mac: The Law of One Price Is Lovin’ Our Little Mac Index
    The “law of one price” holds that identical goods should trade for the same price in an efficient market. To what extent does it hold internationally? The Economist magazine’s famous Big Mac Index uses the price of McDonald’s burgers around the world, expressed in a common currency (U.S. dollars), to estimate the extent to which various currencies are over- or under-valued. The Big Mac is a global product, identical across borders, which makes it an interesting one for this purpose. Yet it travels badly—cross-border flows of burgers won’t align their prices internationally. So in 2013 we created our own index which better meets the condition that the product can flow quickly and cheaply across borders: the Geo-Graphics iPad mini Index, which we hereby rechristen the “Little Mac Index.” (H/T: Guy de Jonquieres) Consistent with our product, iPad minis, being far more tradable than The Economist’s product, Big Macs, our index shows that the law of one price holds much better than theirs does.  The average overvaluation of the dollar according to the Big Mac Index was 19% in January - a Whopper.  The average dollar overvaluation according to the Little Mac Index was a mere 5% - small fries. So what’s happened since we last updated our index in May?  The U.S. dollar index (the DXY) has appreciated nearly 20%.  The rising dollar is lowering U.S. corporate profits and putting downward pressure on U.S. inflation.  Measured in terms of iPad minis, the dollar has over this period gone from being cheap against most major currencies to being expensive – a reflection of the fact that America’s central bank is almost alone in having virtually committed to tightening policy later in the year. One notable exception to the dollar’s strength in the Little Mac Index is the Swiss franc, which will buy you fewer iPad minis than the buck.  The franc skyrocketed after the Swiss National Bank unpegged it from the euro on January 15. When we first launched the index in June 2013, the dollar looked undervalued against most currencies.  Now that the dollar is looking pricey, there is more reason to fear currency conflicts spilling over into the trade sphere.  This is highlighted by the growing threat to a Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) trade deal from U.S. corporate interests seeking to hold it up until anti-currency-manipulation provisions can be welded in.   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • China
    Will China Bail Out Russia?
    Russia’s foreign exchange reserves have fallen by nearly 1/3 since October 2013; they’ve fallen 20% just since September 2014.  Whereas the country still has over $300 billion in reserves, about $150 billion of this may be illiquid; it also has close to $700 billion in external debt. Whom would Russia turn to for dollars in a crisis? The IMF is the most obvious place.  The IMF approved lending to Russia of about $35 billion (SDR 24.8 billion) in the 1990s. With the sort of “exceptional” access that the Fund has granted to Greece, Portugal, Ireland, and Ukraine, Russia could potentially borrow up to $200 billion today, as shown in the figure above.  But when it comes to Russia, the United States and Europe are not in a generous mood at the moment.  Moscow would almost surely want to look elsewhere. What about its new BRICS friends?  Putin had said in 2014 that the new BRICS Contingent Reserve Arrangement (CRA) “creates the foundation for an effective protection of our national economies from a crisis in financial markets." Russia could potentially borrow up to $18 billion through the CRA.  But here’s the rub: it can only do so by being on an IMF program.  Without one, Russia could borrow a mere $5.4 billion – chicken-feed in a crisis.  In fact, borrowing such a pitiful sum might only precipitate a crisis by hinting that one was coming. What about China?  Here, things get interesting.  Under a central-bank swap line agreed in October, Russia could borrow up to RMB 150 billion – the equivalent of $24 billion at current exchange rates. China’s Commerce Minister Gao Hucheng has reportedly said the swap line could be expanded. What would Russia do with RMB, though?  Why, sell them for dollars, of course – as Argentina is apparently prepared to do with the funds received through its swap line from China. China might be happy for Russia to sell the renminbi it receives for dollars, as doing so would put downward pressure on the RMB without implicating Beijing in “currency manipulation.” “Russia plays an indispensable role as a strategic partner of China in the international community,” according to a December 22 editorial in China’s Global Times. “China must hold a positive attitude to help Russia out of this crisis.” In short, China may well have both economic and geopolitical reasons for offering Russia a helping hand.   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Monetary Policy
    Employment Data Suggest Fed Could Be "Patient" Until 2016—or Later
    In its last two statements, the FOMC has said that it “expects inflation to rise gradually toward 2 percent over the medium term”—2 percent being its target rate. What would it take to move it there? We looked at how many different variables correlate with the Fed’s preferred inflation measure—core PCE inflation. Oil and the dollar have been much in the news of late, but their prices have had little relationship with core PCE inflation over the past decade, as shown in the bottom-left figures above. The single variable that seems to correlate best, as seen in the top-left figure, is the employment/population ratio among adults aged 25-54 years. If we follow this ratio’s trend-line since 2013, when it began its last major upturn, this suggests that core PCE inflation won’t hit 2% until late 2016 or early 2017—as seen in the large right-hand figure. If we follow it since its trough in 2011, core PCE inflation does not hit 2% until late 2017. This suggests that a “patient” Fed might not begin hiking rates until considerably later than the market is currently anticipating, which is the middle of this year. A 2016 rise seems more plausible. The Economist: Opportunistic Overheating Wall Street Journal: Fed Flags Midyear Rate Hike-Or Later Financial Times: Dollar Rally Stalls on Rate Rise Rethink Federal Reserve: FOMC January 28, 2015 Statement   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Capital Flows
    Which Countries Should Fear a Rate Ruckus?
    For many Emerging Markets, May 22, 2013 is a day that will live in infamy.  It marks the start of the great Taper Tantrum, when Ben Bernanke’s carefully hedged remarks on prospects for slowing Fed asset purchases triggered a massive sell-off in EM bond and currency markets. Though the sell-off was widespread, it was not indiscriminate.  As the top figure above shows, EMs with large current account deficits were the hardest hit.  These were countries dependent on inflows of short-term capital facilitated by the $85 billion the Fed was pumping in monthly to buy Treasuries and mortgage-backed securities. So who is vulnerable now to a possible Rate Ruckus – an EM bond market sell-off triggered by an unexpectedly early or aggressive Fed rate hike? As the bottom figure suggests, many of the same countries are likely to be in the firing line – in particular, Ukraine, Turkey, South Africa, Peru, Brazil, Indonesia, Colombia, Mexico, and India.  Of these, only Ukraine has seen a significant improvement in its current account deficit, which has fallen from a whopping 9.2% to 2.5%.  Poland and Romania have moderate (2%) but higher deficits, and could receive a larger jolt this time around.  Only Thailand has moved into surplus, and looks likely to be spared. CFR Backgrounder: Currency Crises in Emerging Markets Financial Times: Fed Meeting May Add Pressure to Emerging Markets The Economist: The Dodgiest Duo in the Suspect Six Foreign Affairs: Taper Trouble   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Russia
    Global Economics Monthly: January 2015
    Bottom Line: It is tempting to rush to judgment on the Russian economic crisis. Russian Finance Minister Anton Siluanov is among those declaring the currency crisis over and promising rate cuts to follow currency stability. Conversely, many market analysts have warned of an imminent, full-blown economic crisis including a credit crunch, exchange-rate-driven inflation, sky-high interest rates, and rising unemployment. Both assessments are off the mark. The reality is that these are early days in the crisis; sanctions and oil together are imposing massive economic dislocations and those costs will rise over time as sanctions bind more tightly, limiting the resilience of the Russian economy. Russia still has substantial financial buffers and economic policies that it can use to delay an economic crisis, but market pressures are likely to return sometime in 2015. A Classic Currency Crisis? Recent developments in Russia present many elements of a classic emerging-market crisis. A market selloff and loss in confidence fuels capital flight. Sharp interest-rate hikes (650 basis points) fail to stem currency depreciation (see Figure 1). Investment plunges and consumers race to get out of the currency (for example, through the purchase of durable goods). Against this backdrop, it is not surprising that growth fell in the fourth quarter by 0.5 percent over a year earlier, leading to renewed currency declines. Market forecasts of a 5 percent decline for 2015 now look optimistic. But it would be misleading to view these developments solely through a currency lens. The Russian economy was already struggling prior to the current crisis, as weak economic policies, a poor global environment, and adverse demographics undermined the promise of a strong recovery following the financial crisis. Oil has always been central to Russian economic performance, but weak fiscal policies have meant that increasingly higher oil prices were needed to keep the budget balanced. In 2014, the fiscal break-even price was around $110 per barrel, compared to estimates of $30 to $40 per barrel just a decade ago. With current oil prices around $50 per barrel, the fiscal and external shortfall is substantial and is likely to widen as the government steps in with rescue packages for companies in trouble. Even though a depreciated currency can help the budget by raising the ruble value of exports, fiscal policy looks unsustainable. The most likely trigger for a future crisis resides in the financial sector. December’s $2 billion bailout of Trust Bank, coupled with news of large and potentially open-ended support for VTB Bank and Gazprombank, highlight the rapidly escalating costs of the crisis for the financial sector as state banks and energy companies face high dollar-denominated debt payments and falling revenues. Rising bad loans, falling equity values, and soaring foreign-currency debt are devastating balance sheets. As foreign banks pull back their support, the combination of sanctions, oil prices, and rising nonperforming loans is creating a toxic mix for Russian banks. So far, a crisis has been deferred by the belief that the central bank can and will fully stand behind the banking system. If any doubt creeps in about the strength of that commitment, a run will quickly materialize. Therein lies the central challenge for the central bank. News of large or unexpected bailouts trigger renewed market pressures and risks a political backlash, but the trigger for a crisis may be more closely linked to any sense that the central bank will step back from its support for the system. Figure 1: Central Bank of Russia's (CBR) Key Rate and the Value of the Ruble Source: Central Bank of Russia.   In this environment, further central bank rate hikes are likely to be counterproductive. Capital controls look increasingly likely, even though controls in Russia usually have been ineffective. Options range from those relatively benign to markets (for example, requiring state companies to sell foreign currency holdings) to repressive constraints on private deposits. In the end, evasion is simply too easy. The government has resources: international reserves fell $121 billion last year to a still-healthy $389 billion, but the government’s willingness to spend further is uncertain. Still, Russian policymakers need to do something. Sanctions as a Force Multiplier Sanctions are a force multiplier. Western sanctions have taken away the usual buffers—such as foreign borrowing and expanding trade—that Russia relies on to insulate its economy from an oil shock. Over the past several months, Western banks have cut their relationships and pulled back on lending, creating severe domestic market pressures. The financial system has fragmented. Meanwhile, trade and investment have dropped sharply. These forces limit the capacity of the Russian economy to adjust to any shock. Russia could have weathered an oil shock or sanctions alone, but not both together. This was the argument made by President Barack Obama, who stated recently that “over time [sanctions] would make the economy of Russia sufficiently vulnerable that if and when there were disruptions with respect to the price of oil—which, inevitably, there are going to be sometime, if not this year then next year or the year after—that they’d have enormous difficulty managing it.” Another implication of sanctions is the reduced risk of contagion to the West. Unlike the 1998 Russian crisis, the fact that sanctions have caused Western financial institutions to pull back from Russia makes the West less leveraged, less interconnected, and therefore less vulnerable to contagion than was the case in 1998. It is not surprising, therefore, to see a modest reaction in U.S. markets so far, with the exception of energy companies that are affected by the global energy shock. A Russian Crisis: Are We There Yet? Measured by the severity of recent market moves, Russia is in crisis. But from a broader perspective, a comprehensive economic and financial crisis would cause a far greater degree of financial distress for the Russian people. Companies would find working capital unavailable; interest rates of 17 percent (or higher) and exchange rate depreciation would cause a spike in import prices; and capital expenditure would crater. All this would generate sharp increases in unemployment and a far greater fall in gross domestic product (GDP) than we have seen so far. We are not there yet. Ultimately, though, the test of whether a crisis materializes is as much political as economic: an upturn in inflation and a deep recession would be the real test of whether sanctions would create conditions for peace, not just a move in Russian stocks and bonds. That is because it is only now that the broader Russian public is feeling the costs of President Vladimir Putin’s policies. No doubt the searing experience with hyperinflation in 1998 still resonates with the Russian public. History also reminds us of the fragility of confidence. When crisis happens, exchange rates will move far and fast. But these are early days, and economists should mind the old dictum when it comes to financial crises: predict an outcome or a date, but not both. Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon Greek elections raise market fears Snap Greek elections will continue to unsettle European markets on concerns of a Greek exit from the euro and a renewed European crisis. European policymakers appear overly confident that an exit no longer presents systemic risks. Time for a plan B? Ukraine’s financing gap remains unfilled, amid standoff between the International Monetary Fund and Western governments. Venezuela can't survive low oil With oil prices at current levels, Venezuela appears headed for crisis.
  • Monetary Policy
    Lessons from the Ruble’s Dive
    My thoughts on the ruble’s collapse are here. Three points to highlight in particular: Sanctions are a force multiplier. While oil is the dominant factor behind the ruble’s fall (see figure 1), western sanctions have taken away the usual buffers—such as foreign borrowing and expanding trade—that Russia relies on to insulate its economy from an oil shock. Over the past several months, western banks have cut their relationships and pulled back on lending, creating severe domestic market pressures. The financial system has fragmented, and any doubts that the central bank fully backs bank liabilities will lead to a run. Nonetheless, political pressures on the central bank remain intense. In fact, it was news of a central bank bailout of Rosneft that apparently triggered the most recent round of turmoil. Meanwhile, trade and investment have dropped sharply. These forces limit the capacity of the Russian economy to adjust to any shock. Perhaps Russia could have weathered an oil shock or sanctions alone, but not both together. Analogies to 1998 are too simplistic. Conditions in Russia and the global economy were much different in 1998, as global financial markets were dealing with the legacy of the Asian financial crisis and emerging strains in major money markets, so we shouldn’t overdraw the lessons from that time. Similarly, the fact that sanctions have caused western financial institutions to pull back from Russia makes the west less leveraged, less interconnected, and therefore less vulnerable to contagion than was the case in 1998. Therefore, I am not surprised to see a modest reaction in U.S. markets so far, with the exception of energy companies that are affected by the global energy shock. Further rate hikes are likely to be counterproductive. The central bank has already hiked interest rates to 17 percent and intervened (see figure 2). While they have produced a bounce in the currency, the sense of panic remains. I don’t think further rate hikes are helpful in the current environment. I expect capital controls are the next step, even though the history of controls in Russia is that they are usually ineffective. Evasion is simply too easy. But Russian policymakers need to do something. The real test of whether sanctions work starts now. I have for some time believed that it would be an upturn in inflation, and a deep recession, that would be the real test of whether sanctions would create conditions for peace, not a move in Russian stocks and bonds alone. That is because it is only now that the broader Russian public is feeling the costs of President Putin’s policies. No doubt the Russian’s searing experience with hyperinflation in 1998 still resonates with the Russian public. History also reminds us of the fragility of confidence. When crisis happens, exchange rates will move far and fast. Figure 1: The Ruble and the Price of Crude Oil Source: Bloomberg; Central Bank of Russia Figure 2: The Ruble and Official Central Bank Currency Intervention* Source: Central Bank of Russia *Note that this figure shows only officially reported intervention by the Central Bank of Russia and does not include unreported intervention or intervention carried out by other entities, including the Ministry of Finance.  
  • Monetary Policy
    What Did the Greenspan Fed Do with Its “Considerable Time” Pledge in ’04?
    The big question for the December 16-17 FOMC meeting is whether to drop the pledge to keep rates at near-zero for a “considerable time.” Prior to the last meeting in October, two-thirds of primary dealers expected that language to be modified before the end of the year. Can history be any guide? Eleven years ago, at the January 2004 meeting, the Greenspan Fed faced precisely the same question, with the markets watching intently.  At that time it had been operating for 6 months under a pledge not to raise rates for a “considerable period.” As the figure above shows, measures of core inflation, which the Fed favors, were lower back then.  And unemployment at the time was almost precisely where it is now (except for U-6*, which was lower). And what did the Greenspan Fed do?  It dropped its “considerable period” pledge, saying instead that “the Committee believes that it can be patient in removing its policy accommodation.” If history is a guide, then, the Yellen Fed will drop its “considerable time” pledge on Wednesday, paving the way for a possible rate hike in the middle of 2015.   * Total unemployed, plus all persons marginally attached to the labor force, plus total employed part time for economic reasons, as a percent of the civilian labor force plus all persons marginally attached to the labor force Financial Times: Doves May Be Dismayed by Fed Chairwoman Janet Yellen’s Comments Wall Street Journal: 5 Things to Watch for at the December Fed Meeting The Economist: What Should the Federal Reserve Do? The Case for Opportunistic Inflation New York Fed: The 2015 Economic Outlook and the Implications for Monetary Policy   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”  
  • Europe and Eurasia
    The Politics of IMF Crisis-Country Growth Projections
    IMF GDP growth “projections” accompanying emergency lending programs are nothing of the sort; they are targets the level of which is necessarily set high enough to enable the interventions. Take Greece.  After committing to lending of €30 billion over 3 years in 2010, the Fund projected that the crisis-mired nation would return to growth by 2012.  As shown in the left figure above, Greece’s economy actually plunged by 7% that year – the year it completed the world’s largest sovereign restructuring, covering €206 billion of bonds. Take Ukraine.  After committing to lending $17 billion over 2 years in April, the Fund projected that its civil/Russian war would magically end and its economy bloom – achieving 2% growth in 2015.  Instead, its “adverse scenario” looks to be playing out according to script, with the economy on pace for a 7% decline.  There is now a massive $15 billion gap between what has been pledged by the official sector (IMF, World Bank, European Union, and others) and what is actually needed to fund the government. The point is not that the IMF is particularly incompetent or unlucky; few in the organization’s talented professional staff could be in the least surprised with how Greece and Ukraine have played out.  The point is that the IMF’s growth projections for crisis-hit client countries are deliberately being pegged at levels high enough to overcome its own prohibition against lending to countries that lack sufficient funding to cover government spending over the coming 12 months. This is a sound rule, intended to keep the Fund from getting sucked into the vortex of politics.  Greece’s insolvency clearly required write-offs and gifts; more debt, which is all the Fund has to offer, was never going to resolve the problem.  Ukraine requires at a minimum a cessation of hostilities.  By all means, the EU, U.S., and other friendly nations should step in financially and otherwise to show solidarity, but such is not the proper role of the Fund.  If it manages to avoid major losses on these interventions, it will only do so by having provided political cover for those who will – governments, such as those of Germany and the United States, which should have been up-front with their people about the likely cost and political purpose of their aid. Financial Times: IMF Warns Ukraine Bailout at Risk of Collapse Wall Street Journal: Ukraine Will Need More Bailout Funding, IMF’s Lagarde Says IMF: Ukraine Request for a Stand-By Arrangement IMF: Ex Post Evaluation of Greece's Exceptional Access   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Japan
    Global Economics Monthly: December 2014
    Bottom Line: Many experts hope that December snap elections will reenergize Japan’s structural-reform agenda, but the barriers to implementation remain high. Without progress on this “third arrow” of Abenomics, growth will remain almost fully dependent on easy money, intensifying global currency tensions in 2015. Most analysts are optimistic that this month’s elections in Japan could represent a turning point for the faltering Japanese economy. They argue a strong showing by Prime Minister Shinzo Abe’s Liberal Democratic Party (LDP) will provide a clear mandate to reinvigorate Abe’s structural-reform agenda. Indeed, the polls recently have moved in the LDP’s favor, and now suggest that the government could win well over three hundred seats in the lower house of parliament, nearly a two-thirds majority (the party currently holds 294 seats). Should Abe make economic reform a priority, he appears to have a mandate to make significant progress. Recall that structural reform was the ambitious third arrow of Abenomics, complementing monetary policy (the first arrow) and fiscal consolidation/reform (the second arrow). The government was committed to agricultural reform as part of a Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) agreement, as well as comprehensive labor and product market reforms. Many other governments, as well as market participants, linked their support for Abenomics to this third arrow in hopes of a supply-side effect that would allow a sustained increase in growth. To date, though, little has been accomplished. Given the continuing vested interests and political impediments to reform, my concern is that, though the government will “wave the flag” of structural reform in the coming months, the focus will quickly turn to domestic constitutional reform of the electoral system and regional defense concerns, sapping the energy behind economic reform. The fiscal arrow, in contrast, aimed to restore fiscal sustainability through upfront stimulus coupled with a multistage increase in the consumption tax. However, following weak growth numbers, the consumption tax has been delayed (though the government has committed to an increase in 2017). Although that makes a lot of sense on cyclical grounds, the government will still need to worry about fiscal credibility with government debt already in excess of 250 percent of gross domestic product (GDP). In that case, what is left to drive economic growth? Abenomics, which generated strong support based on its comprehensive three-arrow approach, would be reduced to a single arrow—aggressive monetary easing. A Sea Change for Monetary Policy Japan’s monetary policy is indeed extraordinary. At the end of October, by a five-to-four vote, the Bank of Japan (BOJ) surprised nearly everyone with a dramatic expansion of its unconventional monetary policy, citing renewed risks of deflation. If the program is fully implemented, bond holdings will be over 40 percent of GDP, adjusting for duration of the debt purchased, which is more than twice the size of the Federal Reserve’s three quantitative easing programs between 2008 and 2013. For a small, open economy such as Japan’s, easier money works in large part through the exchange rate. I would not argue that the central bank is aiming for exchange-rate depreciation, but at play is a central bank that—while motivated by domestic considerations—is taking advantage of the Fed’s turn toward normalization to make a dramatic move that ensures a substantial market impact by emphasizing the divergence of policy. As shown in Figure 1, the yen’s recent moves closely track movements in the Bank of Japan’s balance sheet. Japan has experienced sharp fluctuations in the past and there is reason to believe this time will be no different. Although some market commentators would argue that investors are already stretched, holding substantial investments that would do well in the case of a yen depreciation, from a fundamental perspective there is still some way for the yen to fall if the BOJ meets its asset-purchase targets. Still, Japan faces an uphill battle to reach its inflation target. A sharp and continuing decline in retail gasoline prices in yen, as well as the deflationary effect as the earlier consumption-tax hike wears off, has by some measures reduced underlying inflation to below 1 percent. Figure 1: The Dollar–Yen Exchange Rate and the Bank of Japan’s Balance Sheet Source: Bank of Japan; Oanda Exchange Rate Intervention In a coordinated announcement, the Japanese Government Pension Investment Fund (GPIF) announced a shift away from government bonds and toward equities, both domestic and foreign, doubling the share of equities to 50 percent. As a general rule it is not such a good idea to use government wealth funds as an instrument of monetary policy in this way: insurance and savings for future generations should be insulated from the short-term decisions that drive monetary policy. However, given that government policy has skewed previously toward support of the bond market, it can be argued that this is a good move from a longer-run perspective, and it does arguably strengthen the near-term wealth effects of quantitative easing. But it is worth highlighting that from an economic perspective, combining monetary easing with foreign asset purchases is the same as directly intervening in exchange markets, something the Group of Twenty (G20) has clearly opposed. In the context of weak global demand, it is unclear how Japan’s trading partners will respond to a sharp and continuing depreciation of the yen. To date, a number of Japan’s Asian trading partners have expressed concern, but we have not seen significant moves or the advent of a “currency war.” Credit is due to the Chinese government, which has held fire so far. But, amid softening domestic demand (the Chinese government this week lowered its growth target to 7 percent, despite substantial stimulus), any move by China to moderate the pace of renminbi appreciation against the dollar or other currencies as a response to the yen’s move would likely trigger a chain reaction in the region. Europe also will be watching the yen’s move closely. Although there are good reasons close to home for the European Central Bank to ease monetary policy, on the margin the Japanese move contributes to deflationary pressures in Europe. The United States is in a different position. Trade is a relatively small share of its economy, and so even a material appreciation is unlikely to undermine the strong growth outlook and continued strengthening of the labor market. So why worry? Indeed, U.S. policymakers appear broadly supportive of Japanese monetary policy, and see stronger growth in Japan, however achieved, as a positive contribution to the global outlook. The problem is as much political as economic. A sharp appreciation of the U.S. dollar against its major trading partners, driven by expectations that the Federal Reserve will begin to normalize policy while others ease, is bound to be contentious. There could be particular ramifications for trade. Congress is likely to produce a bill granting the president trade promotion authority (TPA), which is essential for any meaningful agreements on TPP or other trade negotiations underway. This case for bipartisanship on this issue is based on the historical Republican support for free trade, and recognition that Democrats have been the primary hurdle to passage of free trade agreements to date. Perhaps optimism is justified, but do not underestimate the risk that negotiations could go off track. In the past, both parties have pressed for tough language requiring any trade deal to address exchange-rate misalignments, and that pressure is likely to mount if dollar strength is seen as a risk for the economy. Such exchange-rate language could be a dealbreaker, as it is hard to see Japan or other U.S. trading partners making the tough concessions needed to agree to these conditions. There is much to commend the Bank of Japan for as it reverses decades of orthodox policy in order to jump-start growth with aggressive monetary easing. But relying on only one arrow presents both economic and political risks at home and abroad. Let us hope that optimism about the structural arrow proves correct. Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon Draghi needs to start acting European Central Bank (ECB) President Mario Draghi has been promising to do whatever it takes to restore growth and achieve price stability, and needs to deliver now, beginning with the ECB’s December meeting. Greek elections loom Snap elections highlight Greece’s continuing economic challenges and could reinvigorate a debate over the adequacy of Europe’s crisis response. Cheap oil burns holes in government budgets Falling oil prices are putting significant pressure on a number of exporters’ government finances, including Russia, Venezuela, and Nigeria.
  • Europe and Eurasia
    Bank Valuations Tank as ECB Flubs Its Stress Test
    Low market valuations (i.e., price to book ratios) for euro area banks reflect market concerns over their capital cushions, opined the Bank of England just prior to last-year’s launch of the ECB stress tests—the long-awaited results of which were published on October 26.  The tests, “by improving transparency,” said the BoE, have “the potential to improve confidence in euro area banks.” So did they? We looked at market valuations just before and after publication of the test results.  As can be seen from the right-hand figure above, they rose sharply, both in absolute terms and relative to the broader market, in the week leading up to publication—a period in which there was considerable speculation that the results would be good.  They were indeed good, with only 25 out of 130 banks failing, but valuations plummeted over the three weeks following publication, in absolute terms and relative to the broader market.  28 of the 31 Euro Stoxx index banks tested now trade at lower valuations than they did before the results were released. Over that three-week period, independent analyses were steadily coming out—among them, ours—criticizing the tests for flaws such as inflated inflation assumptions and over-generous treatment of deferred tax assets as capital.  The ECB’s conclusion that the banks needed to raise a mere €9.5 billion in additional capital was thus not credible, and indeed fell way short of what independent analysts were suggesting. In sum, the ECB has indeed improved transparency, revealing through data publication just how weak the capital base of the euro area banking sector actually is.  But in its unwillingness to call a spade a spade and to do something about it, it has failed to “improve confidence in euro area banks,” as the BoE had hoped it would.  The reason may lie in the fact that public-sector funds are needed but may not necessarily be made available by those that have them—a problem we flagged back in March. The ECB’s failed stress tests thus enter into the euro area’s already crowded stress test Hall of Shame.   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Budget, Debt, and Deficits
    Japan’s Sensible Fiscal Retreat
    Surprisingly poor second quarter growth numbers in Japan have raised market expectations that there will be snap elections and a delay in the consumption tax hike that was scheduled for October 2015. GDP fell for a second consecutive quarter, by 1.6 percent (q/q, a.r), versus market expectations of a 2.2 percent increase. A huge miss. Falling corporate inventories were a large part of the story, but exports rose only modestly while household consumption and capital spending slowed. The yen sold off after the announcement, reaching a low of 117 against the dollar. Japanese stocks are higher. Most G-20 policymakers, concerned about global growth, will salute the move by the Japanese government to avoid a fiscal contraction. David Cameron, notably, saying that “red warning lights are flashing on the dashboard of the global economy”, captured the sour mood of this past weekend’s Brisbane Summit. More directly, U.S. Treasury Secretary Lew, in his speech ahead of the G-20 summit, called on Japan to pay “attention to short-term growth alongside medium-term fiscal objectives. To maintain the recovery and escape deflation, Japan needs to move proactively and decisively to more than fully offset the short-term contractionary impact of the expiration of past fiscal measures and the next consumption tax increase, should Prime Minister Abe decide to proceed with it on the current schedule. The most effective policy would give households short term relief to encourage consumption. A few years ago, in the United States, we implemented a temporary payroll tax holiday to accomplish a similar goal.” He went on to call for a renewed a structural reform effort, the “third arrow” of Abenomics, on which there has been little progress. Other G-20 leaders made similar remarks.  Larry Summers and Paul Krugman reinforced this call for a delay in the tax hike (Paul wouldn’t mind a permanent shift), with the IMF on the other side (though they may soften their view following release of these numbers).  Overall, policymakers are right to be concerned about growth, and in this context, Japan is doing the right thing. The G-20’s cautious endorsement of the delay in the consumption tax hike doesn’t mean that Japanese policy isn’t causing problems for global policy coordination following the recent aggressive monetary easing by the Bank of Japan (BOJ). I have previously endorsed the BOJ’s actions, doubling down on monetary policy, even in the absence of substantial success on the other two arrows of Abenomics. But that means, as far as support for recovery goes—it’s all about the money. A primary channel through which easier money will drive demand is through a significant and continuing depreciation of the yen. The market’s Abenomics (weak yen) trade lives on. One issue that has not received much attention is that, at the same time the BOJ announced its easing of policy, the government pension investment fund (GPIF) announced a shift in its portfolio away from domestic bonds and into domestic and foreign stocks. Combining monetary easing with direct purchases of foreign stocks is the economic equivalent of direct exchange rate intervention, something the G-20 has previously ruled out. Particularly if the Japanese moves bring forth copycat depreciations elsewhere, this will be a continuing issue for discussion in the coming months, and could find its way to Capitol Hill in the context of upcoming debates over trade policy.
  • Monetary Policy
    Paul Krugman Calls for "Weak-Dollar Policy"...Towards Mars?
    Paul Krugman routinely mocks Germany for wanting “everyone to run enormous trade surpluses at the same time.” As Martin Wolf has put it, this is impossible, as “the world cannot trade with Mars.” What we find amazing is that Krugman does not see a similar problem with his latest call for the United States to run “a weak-dollar policy.” Against whom should the U.S. pursue a weak dollar? As today’s Geo-Graphic shows, major economies outside the U.S. are in no condition to support stronger currencies.  Of the G-7 economies, as the main figure above indicates, only the U.S. and Canada – which have the second- and third-highest growth rates – have inflation near the developed-market standard of 2%.  The others, save the UK, have much lower growth and inflation.  The U.S. pursuing a weak-dollar policy towards its G-7 partners, therefore, would appear deeply damaging and misguided. The G-7 represents nearly half the global economy.  As for emerging markets, the small inset graph shows stagnant growth rates after years of decline.  Against this background, it looks difficult to justify a generalized appreciation of EM currencies. In short, we suspect that Krugman’s call for a weak-dollar policy can only mean one thing: currency war with Mars. CNBC: Why Currency Wars Could Stave Off a Fed Rate Hike Wall Street Journal: Fed Minutes Show Wariness Over Global Growth Financial Times: U.S. Dollar Surges After Strong Data WSJ's Real Time Economics: The Return of the Currency Wars   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Budget, Debt, and Deficits
    Global Economics Monthly: November 2014
    Bottom Line: The European Central Bank's (ECB) recent asset-quality review (AQR) and stress test of eurozone banks was an important step. But restarting growth requires stronger macro policies if Europe is to avoid a Japan-style lost decade. That includes a more concerted effort to deal with the sovereign debt overhang that is a threat to consumption, investment, and growth. In my recent Policy Innovation Memorandum (PIM), I argue that the overhang of debt is a critical constraint on growth, and call for debt relief for Europe's periphery. Why now? Partly, I expect debt issues will return to the fore over the coming years as growth stalls, adjustment fatigue increases, and spreads on periphery sovereign debt rise again. In addition, many of the critical policy debates in Europe were sidelined while awaiting the ECB-led AQR and stress test of the major European banks, which was released at the end of October. Supporters hoped that a credible stress test, and the positive market reaction that resulted, would represent a turning point in the crisis and "jump-start" the European economy. "I definitely think the banking crisis is behind us," said Dutch Finance Minister and Eurogroup President Jeroen Dijsselbloem after the release of the report. Such optimism is misguided and dangerous. The AQR and stress test constitute a serious effort to address the capital shortfall and restore confidence in the financial system, but they do not address all concerns. The review sets the stage for the ECB to emerge as the single supervisor and regulator for Europe's major banks, an important—if incomplete—step toward banking union. This effort, however, will not jump-start lending or get Europe growing again. Without growth, how confident can we really be that the crisis is over? Absent more supportive policies, the banking sector cannot regain its health, capital will remain inadequate, and a year from now the stress test may well look unconvincing. In that regard, I agree with Gavyn Davies: the exercise is a "necessary, but far from sufficient, step to fix the low-growth, low-inflation condition that has become the norm in the European economy." Europe's Three Arrows: The Japanification of Europe Concerns about European growth are a growing weight on markets. At the recent International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank annual meetings, there was widespread talk of the risk of "Japanification" of the European economy, meaning a prolonged period of underperforming growth and low inflation. Though there was no consensus, I came away convinced that Europe needs its own version of Japan's Abenomics—its own "three arrows": Monetary policy. ECB sources have been quoted as suggesting that bolder action, including the purchase of government bonds (quantitative easing, or QE), could come before the end of 2014 or at the January 2015 meeting. A narrow majority (Germany is not alone in its opposition) now seems to recognize that current policies are inadequate, but it appears unlikely that the ECB will be proactive or clearly articulate its commitment to QE unless growth and inflation numbers get significantly worse. Forward guidance on policy, as much as the purchases themselves, will provide the real boost in the European case. Fiscal policy. Europe needs a more countercyclical fiscal policy, with greater spending by the surplus countries providing the demand that is missing as the periphery countries continue to consolidate, but it is hard to imagine such coordination on fiscal policy any time soon. The IMF expects European fiscal policy to be broadly neutral in 2015–2016. Structural policies. Although Spain is credited with some significant reforms, the regional reform agenda—including labor-market, spending, and product-market reforms—lags elsewhere in Europe. A comprehensive supply-side reform is needed to raise potential growth, though it should be acknowledged that structural reform often is disruptive politically and economically in the short run. There are two problems here. First, these remedies are well understood by European leaders—the problem is not imagination, but leadership. Europe remains stuck, and it seems that only a crisis can spur the needed response. Second, the downside of the analogy to Japan and the three arrows of Abenomics is that Europe should also address a fourth arrow—the debt overhang—which exerts a continuing drag on investment and confidence. With the stress test complete, now is the time to address this problem as part of a comprehensive pro-growth package. Debt Policy: The Missing Fourth Arrow Across Europe, sovereign debt is higher than it was immediately following the financial crisis. Last year, gross government debt was 175 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) in Greece and 133 percent in Italy; Portugal and Ireland's governments both hold debt stocks over 120 percent of GDP. Meanwhile, household and corporate debt remains high and continues to threaten bank balance sheets. Low interest rates make these debt burdens manageable for now, and have allowed countries such as Greece and Portugal to reenter markets. But with growth through 2015 projected at an anemic 1 percent, this is a problem deferred, not solved. Continued uncertainty over debt will condemn Europe to years of low growth and its attendant ills. Growth projections for the short- and medium-term are far too low to relieve problems like extreme unemployment—in excess of 35 percent for youths in Spain, Greece, Portugal, and Italy—and the social and political instability it can ignite. Continued weak economic performance will only further reduce confidence and investment, possibly widening the premium on periphery sovereign debt. The way out of the growth doldrums resides in forcefully tackling the debt problem. Europe's leaders need to find the political will to launch a structured debt-relief program. In my PIM, I argue that one place to begin is by looking to the Paris Club, an informal group of official creditors that convenes to address debt problems in low- and middle-income countries. Though my European friends hate my analogy to a forum that supports developing countries, clear lessons can be drawn. Specifically, Europe should implement four of the Paris Club's principles. First, rules should be adopted on a case-by-case basis to tailor restructuring programs to a country's income and debt level. Second, predictable debt relief should be conditional on policy performance, including structural reforms, continued progress toward fiscal balance, and programs to address the burden of corporate-sector debt. Third, countries should receive a cutoff date that would delimit the debt eligible for restructuring. In all cases, only debt accrued before that date would be eligible. This makes the country receiving relief fully responsible for any future debt accumulated. Finally, comparability of treatment for other creditors should not be ruled out as needed. The Paris Club framework is particularly important in the case of Europe, where much of the debt is owed to creditors in the official sector. This is particularly true in the case of Greece. At the end of last year, Greece had received a total of nearly 215 billion euros from "the Troika"—a group made up of the European Commission, the ECB (through the European Financial Stability Facility, or EFSF), and the IMF. This amount was equivalent to 108 percent of Greece's 2013 GDP and 62 percent of its total debt stock (see Figure 1). As a result of the 2012 private restructuring, the vast majority of Greece's debt is now owed to official creditors. Resolving disputes among these official creditors will be much easier if a set of rules is in place. In addition, consideration could be given to reducing debt held by the European Central Bank as part of rescue efforts. Citigroup Chief Economist Willem Buiter has an innovative proposal to cancel ECB debt holdings purchased to fund a temporary fiscal stimulus package. The principle also applies to the bonds the ECB has acquired as part of rescue efforts in the periphery. Figure 1: Greece's Troika and Non-Troika Debt, Year-End 2013 Source: European Commission Criticisms of proposals like these often start with a call for realism. It is highly unlikely that Germany and the other creditor countries would agree to commit to debt relief, even if highly conditional on policy reform, because such a commitment would make explicit the costs of sustaining the European Monetary Union with an incomplete set of economic policies. These creditors are concerned by the precedent a major debt-relief effort might set and by the issue of moral hazard (i.e., that easy relief would encourage recipient countries to relax their reform efforts and return to their bad old ways). But making explicit the cost of saving the eurozone with all its current members is simply good governance, as compared to hiding the costs by presuming they will be repaid in full. Further, the moral hazard problem, though a real concern, can be addressed by making relief conditional on performance. Finally, over the longer term, Germany does not benefit from killing its export markets in the periphery. These factors together make a compelling case for a structured program of debt relief. A Lost Decade Now is the time to embark on a comprehensive effort to restart growth in Europe, including a fourth arrow aimed at debt reduction. Low interest rates, the relief provided by earlier maturity extensions, and the confidence that could be achieved from the stress test combine to create a window for action on the debt. A year from now, if growth has not returned, indebted governments will be called on to rescue or shore up weak banks, uncertainty will return, and confidence and investment will be much harder to achieve. Europe needs a rules-based approach to debt relief. The Paris Club is one place to look for guidance to begin setting these rules. The sooner they are established, the sooner Europe will see a return to growth. Otherwise, a lost decade looms. Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon Lame Outlook for the Lame Duck The U.S. Congress faces a long to-do list for the lame-duck session but is likely to achieve little; the international agenda—e.g., IMF reform and trade promotion authority— is likely to be deferred. More Economic Woes for Ukraine and Russia In Ukraine, the IMF team heads out. A large financing gap looms, calling the IMF program into question. Meanwhile, the Russian economy slips into recession. A Global Slowdown October saw analysts marking down their global growth forecasts, a trend likely to continue in November.
  • Europe and Eurasia
    The ECB Fails to Stress Banks Over the One Critical Variable It Controls: Inflation
    Relentlessly falling inflation is bad news for Eurozone banks.  It increases the real (inflation-adjusted) value of borrower debt and the real cost of servicing that debt.  It causes loan defaults, and therefore bank loan losses, to rise. So with Eurozone inflation, currently at a near-record low of 0.4%, clearly at risk of heading into deflationary territory, what did the ECB say was the “adverse scenario” for this year?  Inflation of 1% – more than twice its current level.  This is indefensible; the ECB’s dire scenario for this year is actually much cheerier than the IMF’s baseline forecast, which pegs inflation at 0.5%.  The country-by-country comparison is shown in the graphic above. Disturbingly, at no point through the end of 2016 is the ECB even willing to contemplate the possibility of inflation being less than it already was in September: 0.3%.  This is a serious failure on the part of the central bank, which this month assumes supervisory responsibility for Eurozone banks.  It suggests that the ECB is more concerned with the reputational costs of acknowledging the possibility of deflation than with testing accurately the ability of banks to withstand it.  As the private sector is not privy to the proprietary bank data that would allow such a proper test, the ECB’s failure to address deflation risks raises the critical unanswerable question of how many of the seven banks that barely passed should actually have failed. Buiter: Four Rescue Measures for Stagnant Eurozone Evans-Pritchard: ECB Stress Tests Vastly Understate Risk of Deflation and Leverage Legrain: Yet Another Eurozone Bank Whitewash Financial Times: Bank Stress Tests Fail to Tackle Deflation Spectre Steil and Walker: Restoring Financial Stability in the Eurozone   Follow Benn on Twitter: @BennSteil Follow Geo-Graphics on Twitter: @CFR_GeoGraphics Read about Benn’s latest award-winning book, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order, which the Financial Times has called “a triumph of economic and diplomatic history.”
  • Europe
    Three Central Banks
    Today’s central bank news tells us a lot about the risks and rewards of proactive central banking. The Bank of Japan (BoJ) surprised me (and nearly everyone else ) with a dramatic expansion of its unconventional monetary policy this morning, citing renewed risks of deflation. The BOJ announced (i) an increase in the target for monetary base growth to ¥80 trillion ($730 billion) per annum from ¥60–70 trillion; (2) an increase in its Japanese government bond (JGB) purchases to an annual pace of ¥80 trillion from ¥50 trillion; (3) an extension of the average maturity of its JGB purchases to 7–10 years (3 years previously); and (4) a tripling of its targets for the annual purchases of Japan real estate investment trusts (J-REITs) and exchange-traded funds (ETFs). In addition, and more controversially, the Japanese Government Pension Investment Fund (GPIF) will shift its portfolio away from government bonds and towards equities, both domestic and foreign, doubling the share of equities to 50 percent. As a general rule it’s not such a good idea to use government wealth funds as an instrument of monetary policy in this way, but given that government policy in the past has been so heavily tilted towards support of the bond market, it can be argued that this is a good move from a longer-run perspective, and it does arguably strengthen the near-term wealth effects of quantitative easing. It is also worth noting that the BoJ has followed the lead of other central banks and moved away from date-based guidance (achieving 2 percent inflation within two years of the start of the program, a target that was always optimistic and now quickly slipping out of reach) to a focus on balance sheet targets. That makes sense. There was a fair degree of attention paid to the fact that the vote was 5-4 for easing. For most central banks, such a closely divided vote would be a negative. Here, however, I see decisiveness. As long as we assume BoJ Governor Haruhiko Kuroda can command a majority on critical decisions, which I do, his willingness to move proactively as soon as a majority exists shows strength. There is some speculation in the markets that the BoJ move was given a green light when the U.S. Treasury did not mention yen weakness as a concern in its recent exchange rate report. I think this is oversold as an explanation. What I do see at play is a central bank that--while motivated by domestic considerations--is taking advantage of the Fed’s turn toward normalization to make a dramatic move that, by emphasizing the divergence of policy, ensures a substantial market impact. Today the yen reached a six-year low against the dollar at 112.4 and stocks rose sharply. That said, I would not be surprised to see exchange rate tensions intensify in coming months and feature centrally in upcoming G-7 and G-20 debates. The BoJ’s move could put additional pressure of the European Central Bank (ECB) to act when it meets next week, though few analysts expect a move to purchase government bonds (sovereign QE) until December at the earliest and more likely next year. There may well be a narrow majority for such a move, but in contrast to the BOJ, failure to act (combined with muddy messaging) ensures that monetary policy will continue to provide weak support for the recovery. Europe needs its own “three arrows”, as well as more aggressive action to deal with the crushing debt overhang. Finally, the Central Bank of Russia surprised markets with a 150 bp increase in interest rates, raising the benchmark rate to 9.5 percent from 5.5 percent at the start of the tightening cycle. With inflation at 8.4 percent and rising (against a target of 5.5 percent), and food inflation several points higher, the central bank was pressured to act. However, the currency sold off following the announcement, despite announcement of an oil agreement with Ukraine, reading the move as a sign of a sharply weakening economy and recognition of the limited commitment of the central bank to defend the currency. I think that is right. The economy is headed for a deep recession, capital flight is continuing, and sanctions are more likely to be intensified than eased in coming months.  In sum, it’s hard not to expect that capital controls will soon follow.