Blogs

Geo-Graphics

A graphical take on geoeconomics.

Latest Post

Aging Will Hit China’s Economy Far Harder Than Is Recognized

Aging is not only shrinking the labor force but damaging productivity—and therefore per capita GDP growth. Read More

United States
Trump Steel Tariffs Could Kill Up to 40,000 Auto Jobs, Equal to Nearly One-Third of Steel Workforce
“I want to bring the steel industry back into our country,” declared President Trump last month. “Maybe [things] will cost a little bit more, but we’ll have jobs.” Tariff opponents in Congress and industry, however, have argued that what may be good for steel won’t be good for other industries. Asked why auto manufacturers are so opposed to tariffs if the impact on their costs is minimal, as the administration is arguing, newly elevated Trump trade adviser Peter Navarro was dismissive. “Look, they don’t like this. Of course they don’t,” he said. “What do they do? They spin. They put out fake news. They put all this hyperbole out.” Is Navarro right? To answer, we’ve analyzed historical data to estimate the impact of Trump’s proposed 25 percent steel tariffs on auto sales and employment. For the technically minded, you can follow the details of our calculations in the endnotes. We estimate that an average car requires roughly 1.2 tons of steel to build.[1] Given that tariffs tend to increase import prices (which determine domestic prices) by at least as much as the tariff, we calculate that a 25 percent steel tariff will increase the price of new passenger vehicles manufactured in the United States between 0.5 and 0.8 percent.[2] Now, based on calculations for the sensitivity of auto sales to price, we estimate that such price rises of American-made cars would translate into a decline of between 1.6 and 3.6 percent in global sales.[3] This we illustrate in the top left figure above, which shows our sales projections with and without the Trump tariffs. But what does this mean for American auto jobs? The historical relationship between U.S. auto sales and employment is tight, as shown below. Based on this relationship, we would expect declining sales to result in auto-industry job losses ranging from 18,000 to 40,000 by the end of 2019.[4] This we illustrate in the bottom left figure above. Given that employment in the U.S. auto industry is vastly higher than in the U.S. steel industry, such job losses would swamp any possible increase in steel employment. As we show in the right-hand figure above, the total amount of jobs at risk from Trump’s steel tariffs in the U.S. auto industry alone is equivalent to almost one-third of the entire U.S. steel industry workforce. In short, Navarro is wrong—deeply so. Employment in the U.S. auto industry will suffer from Trump’s tariffs to a vastly greater degree than it could possibly benefit in the U.S. steel industry. Footnotes ^ According to the World Steel Association, the amount of steel required to produce one ton of automobile or auto-part product ranges from 0.2 to 1.0 tons. For our calculations, we use a midpoint range of 0.5 to 0.7 to estimate that an average passenger vehicle of roughly two tons uses between 1.0 and 1.4 tons of steel. An earlier version of this post over-estimated average vehicle steel input and this has been corrected. ^ This estimate assumes that the auto industry will pass steel costs on to consumers and that steel prices in the United States will rise 25 percent due to tariffs. The latter assumption is conservatively based on recent findings that a 1 percent increase in tariff costs, alone, tends to raise import prices slightly more than 1 percent. ^ The boundaries of this range incorporate different methodologies for estimating automobile price sensitivities in recent research. ^ A portion of these laid-off workers who work in auto retail could conceivably be hired later by foreign auto companies exporting to the U.S. that gain market share over domestic producers.
China
Beijing and Shanghai Overbuild Suggests Growth Hit by 2019
“Houses are built to be inhabited,” scolded Chinese leader Xi Jinping at last October’s 19th Party Congress, and “not for speculation.” After a year’s worth of mortgage-rate hikes and new home sale restrictions backing his words, speculation does seem to have lost steam. Since autumn 2016, housing price growth has slowed nationally, hitting zero last year in Beijing and Shanghai—historically China’s frothiest markets. But might prices actually start falling soon?  And if they do, what would that mean for the economy broadly? Despite falling sales, Beijing and Shanghai continue to build at roughly the same pace we’ve seen since 2014—over 50 million square meters per year in total. The result is that the ratio of new construction starts to building sales has soared—as our main graphic above shows. Unless this reverses soon, the law of supply and demand would seem to dictate price falls. Of course, China famously “overbuilt” in the past, only to see massive influxes of rural migrants absorb the excess supply.  Couldn’t the same now happen in Beijing and Shanghai? We think not. Population growth in these two megacities has hovered near zero in recent years, following efforts to curb population growth in each. What might falling house prices mean for the broader Chinese economy? Home values affect consumer spending, and therefore GDP growth, by way of the so-called wealth effect—that is, consumers tend to change spending habits as their assets rise or fall in value. In the United States, according to one Federal Reserve study, for every $100 decline in housing-market net worth consumption tends to drop by $2.50-5.00. If this relationship were to hold for China, where homes represent a far greater portion of household income, we calculate that a modest 10 percent fall in Beijing and Shanghai home prices would knock over half a percent off GDP. The IMF expects Chinese growth to fall from 6.8 percent in 2017 to 6.4 percent in 2019, although house price declines do not appear to be part of their equation. Our analysis suggests that, all else being equal, something below six percent is more likely—with the drag persisting into 2020 and possibly beyond.
  • Europe
    “Doom Loop” Binding Weak Banks and Sovereigns Still Haunts Europe
    One important reason no one talks about Puerto Rico leaving the “dollar zone” is that the island’s banks have minimal exposure to its government’s debt. There is thus no need even to consider introducing a local currency to recapitalize them. Europe is different. Particularly during the immediate crisis years after 2010, banks in southern Europe holding soured private debt loaded up on the “safe” debt of their national governments, while those governments, now facing growing deficits from the downturn, were pledging to backstop the banks. The banks thus became increasingly exposed to falling government bond prices, while the governments in turn became increasingly exposed to worsening bank balance sheets. Weak banks and weak sovereigns propping each other up is a recipe for national bankruptcy. With the European Union finally in a solid economic upturn, this so-called “doom loop” is no longer front-page news. But as our graphic above shows, the problem has not gone away—far from it. In Italy and Spain, banks are still loaded with their respective government’s debt at nearly the same levels they were at the height of the crisis. In Greece, where doom-loop metrics plummeted in 2012-13, after a massive write-down of government debt, they are headed back up, while in Portugal they have been on a relentless climb since 2009. What is to be done? Enter a European central bank task force led by Bank of Ireland governor Philip Lane, which is recommending the launch of a common Eurozone security that could potentially become an EU analog to U.S. Treasury securities. This “safe asset” would be backed by all 19 member states, but would necessarily involve the fiscally stronger ones—Germany in particular—backstopping the weaker ones. Since this could discourage them from becoming more prudent with their financial commitments, the proposal will struggle to gain traction. But something like it is almost certainly necessary to avoid future Eurozone crises.
  • United States
    Did Tax Reform Really Give Walmart Employees a Raise?
    “Thanks to the Tax Cuts And Jobs Act, Walmart—America’s largest employer—is raising wages,” tweeted House Speaker Paul Ryan on January 11. Walmart CEO Doug McMillon was only too happy to embrace the narrative. “[T]he President and Congress have approved a lower business tax rate,” he told employees. “So, we’re pleased to tell you that we’re raising our starting wage to $11 an hour.” As economists, we are admittedly prone to being cynical. But when a CEO whose compensation depends on happy shareholders says he’s giving more of their profits to employees just because those profits are about to get bigger, we go beyond cynicism. We go for the data. As shown in the graphic above, this is the third wage hike that Walmart has announced in the past two years. Each one was preceded by a period of accelerating private retail wage growth—which is precisely what a cynical economist would expect. Firms raise wages when they need to attract and retain workers. But that makes for crummy PR. Much better to share credit for rising wages with lawmakers who cut your taxes. Gives them motivation to keep the goodies coming. It also helps bury the bigger story, which emerged by leak a few hours after the wage announcement: Walmart would be closing 63 Sam’s Club stores, affecting an estimated 9,400 employees. Don’t you just hate cynical economists?