Blogs

Follow the Money

Brad Setser tracks cross-border flows, with a bit of macroeconomics thrown in.

Latest Post

The U.S. Income Balance Puzzle

The long-standing surplus in the U.S. investment income account, often cited as evidence of  “exorbitant privilege,” is receding. It already goes away without the income from profit-shifting by U.S. multinationals.

Read More
China
The Treasury Foreign Currency Report Should Not Be the China Currency Report
There are countries in Asia that could credibly be charged with "manipulating" their currencies. China currently is not one of them.
Trade
Trump's Stimulus Trumps His Trade Policy
It is hard to think of a President more committed—at least rhetorically—to closing the trade balance than President Trump. The usual criticism of his trade policy is that it is overly focused on a single goal—reducing the bilateral, and ultimately the overall, trade deficit, to the exclusion of more traditional goals like liberalization (e.g. expanding trade) or expanding the scope of the traditional rules governing trade. President Trump has made it equally clear he cares about the manufacturing balance.    Yet the results of the first seven quarters of his presidency show, ironically, the limits on what can be achieved through trade policy alone. To be sure, the impact of Trump's new tariffs (on China) and the new trade deal (with Canada and Mexico) aren't in the data yet. President Trump's trade policy for the first six quarters of his presidency consisted of halting further liberalization (by opting not to participate in the TPP) and a set of fairly narrow, sector specific trade cases (steel, solar, washing machines); the really big shift in policy is only now starting.   But, well, the trade actions to date haven’t come close to achieving the turnaround in manufacturing trade President Trump promised. Imports of manufactures are up significantly. (I forecast out the third quarter based on the first two months of data, if China's September numbers are indicative, I may have been too conservative). I used a somewhat unconventional measure to look at changes in the real trade balance. I used the contributions data in the national income and product accounts rather than the trade data directly. And I calculated the contribution each quarter from the national income and product accounts data and then summed the contributions over time. This avoids the difficulties of scaling real trade measures to real GDP (I think) – and takes out the effect of price movement. This allows me to paint a picture about what is happening to different sectors of the economy—manufacturing for example, petrol, and even services (though there isn’t a story in the services data over the past few years)—as well as the overall numbers.* What jumps out in the data on manufacturing trade? Well, two macroeconomic factors. One: The dollar’s 2014/15 appreciation led export growth to stall, and created a significant drag on the economy at a time when overall demand growth was weak. Falling exports added to the pressure on the manufacturing sector created by the fall in oil and agricultural investment (see Neil Irwin of the New York Times). Two: Trump’s stimulus has, as predicted, supported strong import growth—even in the face of Trump’s “America first” trade policy. Yep, so far Trump’s overall policy mix—his combination of stimulative macroeconomic policies and more aggressive trade policy—has delivered a net stimulus of about 1 percent of U.S. GDP to the United States' main manufacturing trade partners. Trump’s stimulus—and the still relatively strong dollar—are making German and Chinese exports great (again). In technical terms, the cumulative contribution of trade in core manufactures (capital goods, autos, and consumer goods in the trade data) has been negative 0.9 pp of GDP over the first six quarters of Trump’s presidency, and based on the data for the first two months of the third quarter of 2017, the cumulative (negative) contribution will soon be over a percentage point of U.S. GDP. Germany, Japan, Korea, China and many others certainly don’t like Trump’s challenge to the existing trade rules. But they all also have—to date—benefited from strong U.S. demand for exports. The recent import surge, when the q3 data is factored in, will have delivered a benefit to them that is roughly comparable in size to the swing associated with the dollar’s 2014/15 rise. We will see what happens when Trump’s tariffs on China take place. Import growth could cool—the full tariffs would cover roughly a quarter of U.S. “core” goods imports (imports of consumer goods, capital goods, and autos). However, the net effect of putting tariffs on imports of around 2.5 percent of U.S. GDP depends on how much trade is diverted to other trade partners. And export growth also looks to be slowing on the back of the dollar’s strength in the last two quarters, weakness in emerging economies and other countries’ retaliation for Trump’s trade action. Reducing your imports doesn’t improve your trade balance if exports also fall. At least for now, though, “macro” factors trump “micro” factors. Trump’s stimulus has had a far bigger effect on the global economy than Trump’s protectionism. Analysts who look at the nominal trade data haven’t observed the deterioration in the trade balance that I have highlighted, at least not yet. The current account balance has also stayed relatively constant. That isn’t primarily because of services. Or even because of the income balance, though the surplus generated by the offshore profits of U.S. firms remains large. The main offset to the quite significant widening of the manufacturing deficit over the last four years has been the U.S. oil boom. Those who argue that the U.S. can never grow through exports (or substituting domestic production for imports) should take close look at the oil sector. Over the last decade, the fall in the real petrol balance (e.g. rising domestic U.S. production relative to U.S. demand) has added close to two percentage points to U.S. growth.    The improvement in the real petrol balance over the last six quarters has been about 0.5 pp of GDP (based on cumulative contributions), roughly half the deterioration in the non-oil goods balance. A payoff from Trump’s policy of “energy dominance”? Perhaps. But it is more likely a function of changes in the oil price, and the evolving cost structure of U.S. production. Fracking the Permian basin (in West Texas and New Mexico) has generated an amazing amount of oil, at a fairly low cost. The shale boom started under Obama—not under Trump—and it was initially propelled by a combination of a high global oil price, a weak dollar, and good old-fashioned American ingenuity. The dominance of macroeconomic factors extends to one other component of the trade balance—tourism (tourism generally accounts for the bulk of the U.S. services surplus with East Asia; many other services, alas, seem to be exported primarily to tax havens***). U.S. tourism imports (Americans taking vacations abroad) rise when the dollar is strong— and U.S. tourism exports (foreign tourists visiting the U.S.) tend to grow when the dollar is weak (e.g. 2005 to 2014). Trump’s more restrictive immigration policies have added some friction at the border no doubt. But the “stop” in tourism exports actually came in early 2015, six quarters before Trump (and a couple of quarters after the dollar moved).   One final point: I framed this as an argument that Trump’s trade policy hasn’t had the expected effect on the trade balance, as the evolution of the trade balance has been driven by macroeconomic factors—the dollar’s strength, U.S. demand growth, and foreign demand growth. It equally could be presented as an argument that the overall macroeconomic effect of Trump’s coming tariffs will be fairly modest so long as the Fed is free to react to any drag on U.S. activity from the tariffs. The aggregate effect on the economy of even relatively aggressive trade action—as Goldman Sach’s economic research team has argued—ends up being fairly small in a standard macroeconomic model, absent a mistake by the Fed or a shock to “confidence.” The sectoral effect, of course, remains significant (ask soybean farmers in the Dakotas). And, well, it is also worth remembering that the impact of the tariffs on China would also be expected to induce changes in China's policy mix. If China responds by using fiscal policy to stimulate domestic consumption demand, that's good for the world. But it stabilizes output by loosening monetary policy, that would typically be expected to result in a weaker currency —which would offset some of the impact of the tariff on China while shifting some of the pressure over to China's trade partners. * Over the grand course of time, the contribution of exports and imports should generally balance out (no country can run a large trade deficit forever, though it is possible to run a modest trade deficit over time so long as the interest rate on a country's external borrowing is modest). A symmetric expansion of trade, if it reflects the healthy development of comparative advantage, raises the overall level of output as both partners specialize in what they do best. Such dynamic gains are by definition not captured in an analysis of the contribution of trade in the national income and product accounts. The national income and product accounts instead draw attention to the impact of trade on demand, and what matters there is the growth of exports relative to imports. Broadly speaking, what the trade data shows is that the U.S. has increasingly specialized in the production of goods and services for the domestic economy, rather than specializing in the production of goods and services for the global market. A drag on demand from trade has a much more negative overall economic impact if it comes at a time when overall demand is weak. ** The q2 data was heavily influenced by both changes in the petrol balance and changes in the food and feeds balance. In fact, the petrol and the “soybean” surge (measured in the food and feed balance) account for the entire increase in U.S. exports in q2. The available data suggests that the surge in soybean exports will reverse itself, but not likely until q4. For my forecast, I assumed 2018 q4 exports fell back to their q4 2017 level. They may be optimistic. *** I am only partially joking. Ireland is the number one destination for a lot of IPR related service exports, the Caribbean is the number one destination for exports of financial services. See tables 2.2 and 2.3 in the BEA's services trade data.
International Finance
Russia, China, and (the Absence of ) Global Funding of the U.S. Fiscal Deficit…
A technical post on the q2 global reserves and balance of payments data … wonky.
  • Puerto Rico
    Will the Proposed Restructuring of COFINA Bonds Assure Puerto Rico’s Return to Debt Sustainability?
    Puerto Rico’s government and the bulk of the holders of Puerto Rico’s Sales tax backed bonds (COFINA) appear to have reached agreement on restructuring terms (details here). The deal will reduce Puerto Rico’s near-term payments, freeing up a bit more money to support Puerto Rico’s reconstruction. But the terms, in my view, still fall short of providing Puerto Rico with a clear path back to debt sustainability.    This is largely because the payments on the restructured bonds rise over time—while Puerto Rico’s capacity to pay may fall over time. It isn’t clear what will support Puerto Rico’s economy once the $80 billion or so from federal disaster relief funds and private insurance payments run out.    The rise in payments on the sales tax backed bonds might be justified if Puerto Rico was paying back the bond’s principal—and thus reducing its debt stock over time (and freeing up borrowing capacity to finance new investment).   But that isn’t what is happening—or rather, it isn’t exactly what is happening. Technically Puerto Rico will be paying back the principal on some of the new sales tax backed bonds it plans to issue—but those payments will be offset by the growing amount Puerto Rico owes on a second bond (a capital appreciation bond) that is lurking in the background. When the $9.6 billion in new sales tax backed bonds issued in the restructuring are paid off, Puerto Rico will still owe….$14.2 billion on its sales tax backed bonds (Exhibit A, see p. 130 of the .pdf). It isn’t hard to think of alternative deal terms that wouldn’t leave creditors that much worse off but that would substantially reduce the long-run risks to Puerto Rico. I hope it is not too late for those alternatives to receive serious consideration.  The COFINA Restructuring   The old sales tax backed (COFINA) bonds in many ways posed the greatest long-term risks to Puerto Rico’s debt sustainability, even though they account for roughly a third of Puerto Rico's tax-supported debt.* Because of the diabolical structure of the capital appreciation bonds, the real burden of the COFINA bonds was actually a lot higher than implied by the $17.5 billion in bonds outstanding in 2017 ($11.5 billion in current interest bonds, $6 billion in capital appreciation bonds).** Puerto Rico faced an increase in debt service over time from around $700 million back to $1.8 billion. And since the bonds had a direct claim on 5.5 percentage points of Puerto Rico’s sales tax revenue, rising debt service would effectively starve the government of funds. So what happened in the restructuring (outlined in exhibit A, p. 130 and appendix B, p. 140)? About $11.5 billion in current interest bonds, with a coupon of almost 6 percent (current interest payments are around $700m), will be swapped into $9.6 billion of new bonds with an average coupon of 4.5 percent. There is some real debt relief in this deal—payments on COFINA bonds fall from the current level in the near term, freeing up funds for the budget. But creditors are also trading up in a couple of important ways. The old bonds were a mix of senior and junior bonds. The new bonds are all senior bonds. The debt reduction (not surprisingly) is coming from the junior bonds, which get equal status with the senior bonds.  The payment structure on the current interest bonds is also being pulled forward—they are all paid off over the next twenty-five years. Payments on the capital appreciation bonds were moved back.  1Accreted value of the CABs is misleading, as payments were pushed back, providing more time for the bonds to grow in value 2See this link. And by reducing the size of the maximum annual payment from $1.8 billion to $1 billion the bond holders substantially increased the strength of the sales tax pledge.   There is an easy way to see this—under the terms of the COFINA deal, the bondholders get first dibs on a 5.5 percentage point sales tax, up to a certain defined amount (the pledged sales tax base). The sales tax now raises close to $250 million per percentage point—so 5.5 percent raises something like $1.5 billion. If that tax didn’t grow over time, well, the bond holders would be in trouble, as under the old payment schedule Puerto Rico has to pay a peak of $1.85 billion or so. By reducing the peak payment, the bondholders made it much less likely that the 5.5 percent sales tax will not generate enough revenue to cover the payments.****  A stronger pledge is worth a lot, particularly for the junior bonds. So in practice the bond holders aren’t giving up quite as much as it seems. They get less cash, but the quality of their security interest has substantially improved. If the deal only consisted of the current interest bond, it basically would work—$500m or so of interest is something that Puerto Rico likely can afford, even taking into account that it will need to pay something on its other bonds. What creates the trouble? Pulling forward the amortizations of the current interest bond, and filling the backend with a new capital appreciation bond. The current $6 billion in capital appreciation bonds are being swapped into a new $2.4 billion capital appreciation bond. But don’t focus too much on the current notional value—capital appreciation bonds (CABs) don’t pay a coupon, so their current value doesn’t represent a current payment burden. They cause problems because they grow in value over time and thus lurk in the background as a threat to long-term debt sustainability. Since the new CAB doesn’t start making payouts until 2044, it also has longer to quietly accrete (to use the technical term of the increase in the value of the bond). At its peak, it rises to $14.2 billion in value, before it is paid off over about fifteen years (in a series of $1 billion a year installments—it really is structured as a series of zeros, technically speaking, though not for tax purposes). That’s less than the old capital appreciation bonds, but still too much. The risk of the new bond, as I see it, is that the amount Puerto Rico needs to pay will double (from under $500 million to $1 billion) over the next twenty years before leveling off (exhibit 3, p. 10). And that rise in payments does not help to reduce Puerto Rico’s outstanding debt stock. With a capital appreciation bond hiding in the background, the amortization payments on the current interest bond are in a deep sense fake, as the capital appreciation bond is growing in value faster than the current interest bonds are being paid off. The increase in payments would be fine if Puerto Rico’s economy could reasonably be expected to double over the same period. That’s the case when for example an emerging economy has just experienced a big depreciation, raising the current value of its foreign currency debt—but also creating a dynamic where the currency should recover in real terms over time. But it isn’t a sure bet for Puerto Rico.   The oversight board is projecting that Maria, and the influx of disaster aid that followed, will in effect jolt Puerto Rico out of its post 2006 torpor. The risk, of course, is that Puerto Rico’s economy fades once the influx of federal disaster funds (estimated to reach close to $10 billion a year at its peak, providing —counting a modest multiplier—something like a $2 billion plus boost to Puerto Rico’s economy; see exhibit 9, p. 20) goes away.   Think of it this way: right now, Puerto Rico isn’t paying the bulk of its debt and it is receiving large sums of federal disaster funding (including $4.8 billion in additional Medicaid funding). In the future, Puerto Rico will need to pay the new debt that emerges out of the restructuring and it won’t benefit from the disaster funding. The next five years should be fine. The five years that follow might not be. What’s frustrating to me is that there are fairly obvious alternative payment structures on the new sales tax backed bonds that would leave Puerto Rico in a much more sustainable position.   Take one simple alternative: replacing the new capital appreciation bond with an equivalent amount of current interest bonds for example, and amortizing these bonds over 40 years.   Increasing the amount of current interest bonds would raise the interest payment on the new bonds to $540 million—above the level in the proposed deal, but below what Puerto Rico pays now. And in a pure amortizing structure (discounted at 4.5 percent) Puerto Rico would need to pay a flat $650 million a year—but that would be enough to pay the bond off entirely over forty years (and cut its value by a third over twenty years). That is less than Puerto Rico now pays into the COFINA trust, and far less that it has to pay in the future under the proposed new structure. And it is the kind of deal that is robust against the most obvious risk that Puerto Rico faces, namely that it falls back into long-term stagnation, with a high rate of out-migration limiting its future economic size (and debt servicing capacity). And it provides a clear path back to the kind of debt load that would be consistent with eventual statehood as well. Creditors wouldn’t be that much worse off in this structure—they get a bit more cash up front.   The negotiations over COFINA were heavily driven by the terms of the legal settlement over the sales tax pledge—together with the governor and the board’s still fairly optimistic assumptions about long-run growth. No one seems to have imposed a strong debt sustainability overlay on the new deal. If the governor really wants to have a realistic path to statehood, he needs to make sure Puerto Rico’s isn’t out of line with that of the more indebted states—but the call here ultimately rests with the board, which needs to certify that the restructuring is done on terms consistent with Puerto Rico’s long-term sustainability. Assessing Overall Debt Sustainability That leads to the most important, and most difficult, question: what would a sustainable debt payments profile for Puerto Rico look like? Right now, the debt sustainability analysis in Puerto Rico’s latest fiscal plan—and in the COFINA fiscal plan—is thin. The COFINA debt sustainability analysis essentially just showed that the projected sales tax pledge covers the bond's projected payments, with no analysis of how the pledge would impact Puerto Rico’s overall finances if sales tax revenue doesn’t grow as projected and no clear assessment of how much would be left over for other creditor groups. To assess Puerto Rico's debt sustainability, I think it helps to lay out two strong presumptions to help simplify a complicated debate. The first is that Puerto Rico’s sustainability shouldn’t hinge on an assumption that Puerto Rico’s capacity to pay will rise over time. The payment profile on the debt consequently should be fairly flat—unless the payment on a portion of the debt is contingent on growth and truly poses no burden if Puerto Rico’s economy stalls when disaster relief funds run out. The second is that Puerto Rico should be aiming to keep overall payments relative to tax revenues on its tax supported debt in line with that of the fifty states (particularly after 2022, when disaster aid falls off and Puerto Rico has to stand on its own two feet).    Let’s go through the argument for both.*** Why should the board assume that Puerto Rico’s payment capacity won’t rise substantially over time? After all, economies do normally grow, at least in nominal terms. 1. Puerto Rico’s economy was shrinking before Maria. One lesson the IMF has learned painfully over time is that assuming that past trends don’t reassert themselves is dangerous. The available studies on the long-term effects of natural disasters also aren’t encouraging. 2. Demographics aren’t going to work in Puerto Rico’s favor. Even without further out-migration, Puerto Rico’s population will shrink (the board forecasts it will fall from 3.4 million pre-Maria to about 3 million in 2022, and further falls are a given as a result of a low birth rate and past out-migration). And so long as workers can earn more—and get more federal benefits—in Orlando than San Juan, a certain fraction of the rising cohort of new Puerto Ricans will move off-island. A natural decline in the working age population of around 1 percent a year could easily turn to 2 percent.  3. Federal aid falls off a cliff in five years. The $4.8 billion in extra Medicaid funding actually expires earlier, but the governor and board now expect other federal aid disbursements to ramp up as the Medicaid funds fade. The sharp fall off in overall help is now projected to start after fiscal 2022—and the fall off in funding then is steep (p. 20 of the fiscal plan). The board’s forecasts, I think, assume that the fall off in Federal disaster funding isn’t a permanent shock to growth and output. That’s too optimistic in my view. The significant rebound in tax collections that followed the most recent influx in federal aid won’t last forever, so the fall in federal funds also directly impacts the budget.****    4. Puerto Rico’s economy still relies heavily on pharmaceutical manufacturing, and the long-term commitment of the pharmaceutical sector to Puerto Rico isn’t clear after the new tax reform. Puerto Rico’s government also relies heavily on taxes on the pharmaceutical sector and a large software firm that once upon a time produced floppy disks in Puerto Rico—companies that are often in Puerto Rico more for tax reasons than because they really need to be in Puerto Rico. The current tax reform—and the future tax reforms needed to fix the holes in the current tax reform—pose a risk to Puerto Rico. 5. The gains from structural reform are uncertain. There is no doubt that Puerto Rico has room to improve the efficiency of government services, and to make it easier to do business on island. Projecting those reforms will raise the level of output by a couple of percentage points over time is reasonable. But assuming that often painful reforms can offset the drag from the future loss of federal funds and permanently change Puerto Rico’s trend growth is a risk. They could. But if the gains are less than expected and don’t offset the demographic headwinds, Puerto Rico could be in real trouble.  Legally binding increases in payments worry me, as the payment increase is far more certain than the improvement in Puerto Rico’s capacity to pay. I consequently believe the growth baseline that the board uses to assess sustainability should be fairly conservative, with only modest assumed nominal GNP growth.  So much for the slope on the payment curve. What is a reasonable overall level of payments? This is all an art more than a science, but one key benchmark should be the level of debt service relative to Puerto Rico’s own revenues. The state average is around 4.5 percent. New York pays 8 percent. The most indebted states, on average, pay just over 9 percent (exhibit 20, p. 36). Puerto Rico’s revenues —using the board’s definition of the entities that make up the commonwealth, net of federal aid—are expected to rise to $15 billion over the next few years (Exhibits 13 and 14, pp. 25-26). Keeping Puerto Rico's debt service in line with the average state implies overall payments of close to $0.7 billion a year, keeping it in line with say New York would imply payments of $1.2 billion a year, and keeping it below the average of the most indebted states would imply holding payments under $1.4 billion a year. The high end of that range scares me. Benchmarking Puerto Rico against Massachusetts and Connecticut is risky. Poorer parts of the country likely have less capacity to support high levels of debt than rich states. And Puerto Rico's core tax revenues are actually well below total revenues. The commonwealth—focusing on the revenues that are central to the General Fund’s budget—historically has struggled to collect $10 billion in tax, even counting the tax revenues siphoned off in various revenue pledges that backed the debt that was designed to stay off the formal budget. Look at the fiscal 2018 numbers, which, to my surprise, benefited as much from post-Maria disaster aid than they were hurt by the immediate after effects of Maria.  Puerto Rico collected something like $2.5 billion in sales tax (counting funds that went into the COFINA trust for future debt service), around $2.0 billion in individual income tax,***** $1.5 to $2 billion in corporate income tax (an unusually high number thanks to disaster funding, see p. 27), $1 billion in gasoline and auto taxes (also an unusually high number), $0.5 billion in alcohol and tobacco taxes, and something like $0.25 from Puerto Rico’s share of the federal rum tax. To get tax revenue up to $10 billion, you need to include the roughly $2 billion Puerto Rico currently extracts out of the pharmaceutical and software sectors (thanks to Act 154 and non-resident withholdings). It is hard to get large amounts of tax revenue out of a poor population, and there are limits to Puerto Rico’s ability to use things like university fees to pay debt service. The “true” tax base of Puerto Rico is modest: Puerto Rico cannot rely on the continued willingness of the United States to in effect let Puerto Rico win in a game of tax competition.  For those sovereign analysts used to thinking of the level of debt service relative to GNP, $1.0 billion is roughly 1.5 percent of current GNP, $1.4 billion is about 2 percent of GNP and $2 billion is around 3 percent of GNP.  What’s the risk of pledging a large part of Puerto Rico’s tax base to future debt service (especially if all other debt benefits from a specific revenue pledge that is designed to be bankruptcy remote)?  Simple: A big gap between what Puerto Ricans pay in tax and what they receive in government services could mean more out-migration, as Puerto Ricans can avoid paying these taxes by moving to Florida. The negative impact of a large debt service burden though isn’t really in the board’s economic forecast, thanks to a host of very technical modelling assumptions (the board’s economic model assumes that fiscal consolidation only temporarily reduces output, so a bigger primary surplus has no impact on long-term growth; there is no hysteresis effect). The only way to make Puerto Rico sustainable then would be to have the federal government provide more help—as Puerto Rico’s taxes won’t be available to pay for essential government services. That starts to look a bit like the Federal bailout that Congress wanted to avoid. The sales tax backed debt accounts for just over a third of the tax supported bonded debt ($17 billion of $45 billion). The constitutional bonds have a similar share of the total debt (the Puerto Rico Building Authority (PBA) debt has constitutional status along with the listed GO debt). Holders of the constitutional debt will no doubt argue for a mirror image deal that would raise Puerto Rico’s debt service to $2 billion even if the more junior bonds get zero. That is substantially too high in my view: it would put Puerto Rico's debt service well above that of any state.    In other words, the COFINA deal, as currently structured, only works if other groups of creditors get relatively little. There is an enormous gap between the tone of the articles that have looked back at Maria a year on, and the optimistic forecasts that are embedded in the economic plans that are being used in the restructuring deals that Puerto Rico is negotiating with various groups of creditors. If Puerto Rico's growth disappoints, the proposed $1 billion in annual debt service on the sales tax backed bonds on its own would leave Puerto Rico with a higher debt service burden than an average U.S. state. That’s why I think it is important to keep the long-run payment commitment to COFINA under $700 million—and why I hope the alternative deal outlined here isn’t rejected as out of hand.   *Puerto Rico's tax supported debt can be broken into three broad buckets: the sales-tax backed bonds, the constitutional "GO" bonds (which have special protection under Puerto Rico's constitution and were in theory subject to a limit on their issuance) and the rest, a set of bonds that are either subject to clawback and thus junior to the "GOs" or that are explicitly junior. The likely junior claims include: the highway bonds ($4 billion), the pension obligation bonds ($3 billion), the rum bonds (PRIDCO, $2 billion), the conventions and UPR bonds ($1 billion) and the very junior bonds of the public finance corporate ($1 billion). The GDB’s estate also has over $2 billion in junior loans to the highways authority and other entities that I think remain outstanding. Pick your number on the recovery of this bucket… **The capital appreciation bonds have a near nuclear structure. They aren't consistently disclosed (Capital Appreciation Bonds: “are only shown in a footnote on the balance sheet of the issuer; it is not required that they be shown as a liability or expense since there are no current interest payments. This can serve to hide the future liability”), they raise almost no money when they are sold and they give rise to large future claims. The “headline” number for the size of the COFINA claim thus is a little deceptive. The real debt burden is higher. While the GOs posed the biggest short-term legal risk to Puerto Rico after a default (Puerto Rico owed about a $1 billion in principal and interest on the GOs, funds that might be pulled straight out of the budget), the rise in COFINA debt service from $0.7 billion a year (in 2015) to $1.8 billion a year (by 2040) was going to be a source of enormous pressure on Puerto Rico’s treasury.  ***Revenue from the 5.5 percent sales tax is projected to grow from $1.4 billion to over $2.5 billion over the next twenty years, assuring that there is enough to cover $1 billion in debt service. (exhibit 19, p. 30). That though isn’t an assessment of the risk to Puerto Rico’s sustainability of this pledge, as in bad states of the world Puerto Rico bears the downside (it gets less revenue out of the sales and uses tax, so a higher fraction ends up going to the pledge—there is no risk sharing). ****The fiscal plan makes clear that nearly every single tax line item has been influenced by the disaster funding. Corporate income tax receipts notably have increased because of payments from contractors who set up Puerto Rican subsidiaries. Debris removal uses a lot of gasoline, so gasoline tax revenues (clawed back from the Highway bonds) have soared. Insurance funds have led to a surge in car purchases, and thus auto tax revenues. As a result of these revenues, and the Medicaid funding, Puerto Rico didn’t experience the fall off in tax revenue that was initially feared, and didn’t need a Treasury/FEMA fiscal bridge loan. *****If Puerto Rico fully replicated the federal EITC in its tax code, its income tax revenue would fall to just around $1 billion. The absence of federal income tax on personal income earned in Puerto Rico isn't the boon that some argue, as the progressive structure of federal income tax implies the federal government would collect relatively little tax out of Puerto Rico.
  • China
    How Did China Manage its Currency Over the Summer?
    China still manages its currency. That’s hardly a shocking statement, I know. But I don’t fully subscribe to the view that China’s depreciation in the summer was simply a market move, given the dollar's broad strength.   If China’s currency appreciates, that means that China’s authorities decided to allow the appreciation—and not enter the market to block “market” pressure to appreciate. And if China’s currency depreciates, that means that China’s authorities decided to allow the depreciation, and not enter the market to block “market” pressure to depreciate. The key isn’t the market pressure, at least not on its own. It is the decision by Chinese authorities to allow the market pressure to push the currency to a new level.   That’s why—as the Economist's Buttonwood notes this week—there is real information value in the price of the yuan. "When the yuan moves, it carries rare news— about currency demand, about China and by extension about the world economy." And that’s also why there is information in the scale of China’s intervention in the foreign exchange market. If China is resisting market presure, in either direction, it should show up somewhere on the state's balance sheet. Those proxies for China's true intervention are currently telling two stories: China is still using intervention—though on a more modest scale than in the past—to help define the yuan’s trading range (against the basket I assume). China's intervention is currently being done in a less transparent way than in the past, as it is largely coming through the state banks rather than the PBOC.   The most straightforward way to assess China’s intervention is to look for changes in the value of the foreign exchange reserves the People’s Bank of China (PBOC) reports on its balance sheet. Those reserves are reported at historical purchase cost. The change in the reserves thus provides a measure of intervention. And the PBOC’s balance sheet (the changes in the PBOC's balance sheet are the yellow line on the graph) has been absolutely flat this year.   Too flat in a way.   It isn’t clear, for example, what is happening to the interest income that China receives on its massive stock of reserves. It doesn’t seem to be entering into the PBOC’s balance sheet in any obvious way these days. You would think the PBOC’s balance sheet would be growing by something like $50 billion a year just based on the interest on its reserve stocks.* The activity over the spring and summer has showed up only in the settlement data (the black line in the graph)—a data set that aggregates the activities of the state banks and the PBOC. The easiest interpretation of a gap between the “settlement” data and the PBOC balance sheet is that the gap reflects the activities of the state banks (before 2015, China published a useful data series on the foreign exchange position of the banking system—but, alas, that data series disappeared after the August 2015 depreciation. I still miss it…) And it looks like the state banks bought $20 billion of foreign exchange in both April and May. That in effect set a cap on how far the Chinese would allow the yuan to appreciate. The state banks then sold some dollars forward in July, and also sold about $10 billion in foreign exchange in August. That—along with other signals from the Chinese authorities (the counter-cyclical factor, the increase in the reserve ratio on forwards, a rising premium in the offshore forward market that raised the cost of shorting the yuan) helped end the depreciation of June and July. The yuan now looks to be effectively managed against a basket, with an (undeclared) band between say 92 and 98 on the CFETS basket. That at least is what I would infer from China's pattern of intervention over the last 18 months. There is one other point that is worth making: while China still intervenes to manage its currency, the amount of intervention that has been required to keep the yuan within the authorities’ band has been pretty modest recently. By Chinese standards, $10-20 billion a month is nothing… That reflects the fall in China’s current account surplus. The surplus in manufactures remains large, to be sure (as the IIF's Robin Brooks has emphasized). But higher commodity prices have reduced (for real) the overall goods surplus. And more tourism and changes in the way tourism spending abroad is estimated have dramatically increased China’s tourism deficit.** There isn’t a massive gap between export proceeds and imports (so long as the tourism “imports” are all real).   And over the last year, the financial account has generally been close to balance. Cracking down on Anbang and HNA led to a big fall in outward FDI. Sizable inflows into Chinese government bonds have helped to balance ongoing private outflows (which show up in the errors and omissions line). And the banks, in aggregate, are now borrowing abroad to fund much of their lending abroad. They no longer are generating a net outflow. That makes China’s decision about how to manage the yuan as the United States escalates its tariffs—with a potentially giant increase in January—all the more interesting. A weaker yuan is the obvious way to offset a negative export shock, and it is an easy way to try to counter the Trump administration’s actions—especially once China is in a position where it cannot match Trump’s tariffs dollar for dollar.    But letting the yuan go through the bottom edge of the range that the PBOC has—more or less—established over the past two and a half years might upset expectations. There was a sense over the summer that China would likely step in to limit depreciation at the 91 or 92 market (on the CFETS basket) and at around 6.9 to the dollar. That helped keep the broader market calm.   If the yuan were to fall through those barriers, there isn’t an obvious limit to how far it could fall. Global markets might get nervous. Finally, letting the yuan weaken would put a lot of pressure on other emerging market currencies. China doesn’t have a lot of foreign currency debt, at least not relative to the size of China’s economy (the banks are borrowing abroad to lend abroad, so they are hedged; some property firms though aren’t and could be in trouble). But some other emerging markets do have a problem with foreign currency debt and wouldn’t welcome a Chinese decision that puts further pressure on their currencies.    And, well, letting the yuan weaken in response to U.S. tariffs helps China export more to Europe and Japan—and they might not put all the blame for a new China exchange rate shock on the United States. Makes for an interesting choice.   Even though China doesn't meet two of the three criteria that the U.S. Treasury has set out to evaluate when exchange rate management crosses the line and becomes manipulation,*** the way China manages its currency still matters for the United States—and for the world.   *It would be great if the interest income was sold for CNY and remitted back to the budget—that’s what I think countries with large reserves should do. Yet the balance of payments data has shown $20-30 billion in reserve growth a quarter ($110b, or almost a percentage point of GDP, in the last four quarters of data), and the most obvious explanation for the difference with the PBOC’s balance sheet is that interest income isn’t entering into the PBOC’s ticker. That then raises the question of how interest income does enter into the balance sheet…     **I was looking back to see if China’s current account surplus exceeded 3 percent of GDP in 2014 and 2015. That's the U.S. Treasury's threshold for assessing manipulation these days. It now doesn’t. But it did back at the time. The $100 billion jump in China’s tourism imports in 2014 (from methodological changes in the compilation of the balance of payments data) came at a very convenient time. ***There is a conceptual difficulty with Treasury’s criteria that is worth noting. The criteria were developed to capture countries that blocked appreciation through heavy intervention—a coherent, clear definition of manipulation that hasn’t been consistently applied in the past. They won’t capture a country that in effect manages its currency down—as the process of carrying out a managed depreciation burns through reserves. Think of it this way: if China let its currency depreciate to 90 vs. the basket (or 7 vs. the dollar), Chinese residents might start to expect that China wanted further weakness, and move funds out of the yuan. Controlling the depreciation, once it gets started, can require selling a lot of reserves—and the 2015 definition of manipulation is entirely focused on reserve purchases. I suspect that this would prompt the Trump administration to dust off the 1988 definition of manipulation (weakening a currency to gain a competitive advantage in trade). But that too has problems, as China could respond to concerns that it is guiding its currency down by just letting the yuan float down…the reality now, I think, is that it is in the United States’ interest for China to continue to manage its currency for a while longer.