Asia

Thailand

  • Southeast Asia
    In Southeast Asia, Belt and Road Attracts Takers, But Skepticism is Rising
    Since China’s Belt and Road Initiative was formally launched in 2013, Southeast Asia has been one of the major priorities of the infrastructure investment project. Beijing launched a new high-speed railway from Kunming to Laos (a line that is supposed to eventually stretch through Southeast Asia), a high-speed rail link connecting Kuala Lumpur and Singapore, and multiple other projects throughout the region. The giant infrastructure project still has many fans in Southeast Asian governments, and in Southeast Asian private companies. Laos’ government is pushing forward with the $5.8 billion railway, which it has touted as critical to transforming Laos into a transport hub for the region, to spark growth in parts of the landlocked state, and also to boost tourism in the country. According to the Nikkei Asian Review, at the recent Future of Asia conference held in Tokyo, Laotian Prime Minister Thongloun Sisoulith touted the rail as a project “of great importance” to the country’s development, downplaying concerns raised by some financial institutions of the railway’s potential debt burden; Laos could wind up assuming most of the cost of the $5.8 billion project, and piling up unsustainable amounts of debt. Meanwhile, Philippine President Rodrigo Duterte, among other Southeast Asian leaders, has continued assiduously wooing Belt and Road projects and other infrastructure investments from Beijing. Indonesian president Joko Widodo, too, apparently continues to see Chinese infrastructure investment and financing as critical to his plans to upgrade Indonesia’s aging physical infrastructure. But in recent months, leaders and publics in some Southeast Asian states have become worried about the potential downsides of Belt and Road investments. Leaders in Southeast Asia are surely aware of the situation last year in Sri Lanka, in which the country, increasingly dependent on Chinese financing, wound up giving China a 99-year lease on the important port of Hambantota, in order to get a reduction in Sri Lanka’s debts. As the Nikkei noted, even International Monetary Fund head Christine Lagarde warned, in April, that some Belt and Road projects—mostly delivered through loans and not grants—could wind up saddling recipient developing countries with debt traps, unable to repay Chinese state firms and lenders back in the long run. Such concerns in Southeast Asia about Belt and Road remained relatively muted until recently; many countries do indeed need infrastructure investment, did not want to alienate their biggest trading partner, and were waiting to see how Belt and Road’s specific initiatives developed. But now, several of the largest Southeast Asian states—countries with close trade ties with Beijing—are voicing concerns. Before the Malaysian opposition’s surprise victory in May elections, now-Prime Minister Mahathir Mohamad vowed to take a new look at many China-backed projects in Malaysia, including the Kuala Lumpur-Singapore rail line, to scrutinize how much they benefit Malaysia, how essential they are, and whether they involve wasteful spending. Although Mahathir and Anwar Ibrahim, who may be the next prime minister after Mahathir, have promised to maintain a strong relationship with China—Malaysia is China’s biggest trading partner in Southeast Asia—they are still expected to review multiple deals with Beijing. In Thailand too, a country that has become much closer to China economically and strategically over the past decade, some government leaders appear to be reassessing the value of Belt and Road projects. Thailand had promised to link up its eastern seaboard development project with Belt and Road initiatives, and also had welcomed the high speed line. But other countries’ Belt and Road debt problems, and the potential high cost and high debt associated with the rail line, could have soured the junta government on these Chinese initiatives. Construction has finally started on the rail line through Thailand, but this month the Thai government announced that it was, with other Southeast Asian states, considering launching a regional investment fund. The fund may be similar in some ways to Belt and Road (albeit on a much smaller scale)—a possible sign that Thailand wants to promote modest Belt and Road alternatives. The region’s smallest states, like Laos, have become so heavily dependent on China that they may feel they have no choice but to accept Belt and Road projects and other China-backed initiatives, even if they come with debt worries. But larger, more powerful economies may, at this point, be ending their honeymoon with Belt and Road.
  • Thailand
    Previewing the U.S. Treasury’s April Foreign Exchange Report
    The U.S. Treasury Department’s next foreign exchange report is due on April 15—so it should come out soon, maybe even tonight. Normally the section on China attracts all the attention. But right now there isn’t any reason to focus the foreign exchange report on China. China has neither been buying or selling large quantities of foreign exchange in the market—and, well, the yuan did appreciate a bit in 2017. China no doubt still manages its currency but it isn’t obviously managing its currency in a way that is adverse to U.S. economic interests. And China’s loose macroeconomic settings have kept its current account surplus down even though China’s industrial policy seeks to displace imports with domestic production. I worry about what may happen if China tightens excessively before it stops saving excessively—but that isn’t an immediate concern. The real Asian interveners right now are China’s neighbors—Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, and Singapore. All bought foreign exchange on net in 2017, and all also run sizeable current account surpluses. Korea’s surplus is well above 5 percent of its GDP; Taiwan, Thailand, and Singapore all run surpluses of over 10 percent of their GDP. Combined these four countries run a current account surplus of close to $250 billion—bigger, in dollar terms, than either China or Japan. And they all have plenty of fiscal policy space: they could rely more on domestic demand and less on exports. Singapore isn’t going to be in the report—it is intervening rather massively (also see Gagnon), but it gets an unwarranted free pass as a result of its bilateral trade deficit with the United States (a deficit that likely reflects some tax arbitrage, as firms import into Singapore to re-export). So I will be most interested in what the Treasury has to say about Korea, Taiwan, and Thailand. Thailand is the most interesting case. It hasn’t been traditionally covered in the report as it wasn’t considered a major trading partner. But in 2017 it met all three of the criteria that the Treasury has set out to determine if a country is manipulating: a bilateral surplus of more than $20 billion, a current account surplus of more than 3 percent of GDP, and intervention in excess of 2 percent of GDP. Thailand’s bilateral surplus just topped $20 billion, but it easily meets the other two criteria with a current account surplus of 11 percent of its GDP and intervention of 8 percent of GDP. I personally think the Treasury should go ahead and name Thailand and give the Bennet Amendment process a test. There is more than a bit of flexibility in the determination of who counts as a major trading partner. And there is a more intermediate option—the Treasury could indicate that it plans to expand the report’s coverage in October and indicate that if Thailand doesn’t change its policies, it would likely meet all three of the Bennet amendment criteria. It would be rather disappointing if the Treasury simply sticks to its current list of major trading partners (and leave Thailand out entirely). The changes introduced to a designation under the Bennet amendment were designed to make designation (technically, designation for enhanced analysis) a live option. The actual sanctions are quite mild (arguably too mild) and only come into play after a year of negotiation. And the available sanctions on the Bennet list stop well short of any new tariffs. In some ways, Thailand is easy. It hasn’t tried to hide its activities in the foreign exchange market and a strict by the books application of the criteria set out in 2015 would lead to the conclusion that Thailand should be named. It has let its currency, the baht, appreciate over the last year (most currencies have strengthened against the dollar) but the scale of both its intervention and its current account surplus stands out. Korea and Taiwan are harder. Both have long been subject to scrutiny in the foreign exchange report. And both have become adept at adopting domestic policies that encourage large capital outflows and thus reduce the need for headline intervention. Korea channels a significant fraction of the buildup of funds in its social security fund (the national pension service) into foreign assets. And Taiwan has allowed its life insurers to buy a ton of foreign assets—loosening limits on foreign exchange exposure in the process (a new note by Citi's Daniel Sorid and Michelle Yang estimates that the life insurers have added $300 billion to their foreign assets in the last five years, bringing their total foreign portfolio up to $480 billion/65 percent of total assets). As a result of these “structural” outflows from regulated institutions, both Korea or Taiwan have been able to keep their intervention, using the Treasury's methodology, under the 2 percent of GDP threshold in recent years. Taiwan, though, is close and it has never disclosed its activities in the forward market, so there is a possibility that it actually violates the intervention criteria.*    And this is a case where methodology matters. The Treasury deducts estimated interest income from estimated reserve growth, which helps Taiwan a lot given Taiwan's enormous stock of reserves. A simple estimate that takes reported reserve flows in the balance of payments and adds in the reported change in the forwards book puts Korea over the threshold in 2013 and 2014 (before the Bennet criteria were articulated) and would put Taiwan just over 2 percent of GDP.** A by the books application of the Bennet criteria thus would let both Korea and Taiwan off. Treasury could say that neither meets all three criteria and more or less be done with it—perhaps adding that both the won and the new Taiwan dollar appreciated against the U.S. dollar in 2017.  Treasury will of course laud Korea for agreeing to more disclosure in the renegotiated KORUS and ding Taiwan for failing to disclose its forward book or any of the other details that should be disclosed if it voluntarily committed to live up to the IMF’s standard for reserve disclosure. Calling for transparency around intervention is squarely within the Treasury’s comfort zone. But in this case going strictly by the book would ignore what I think is the real issue. Both Korea and Taiwan are currently intervening to cap the appreciation of their currencies—Korea at 1050 to 1060 won to the U.S. dollar, and Taiwan at around 29 new Taiwan dollars to the U.S. dollar. To be fair, both have shifted the intervention range up a bit in 2018—in early and mid-2017 Korea intervened at around 1100 (it shifted a bit in late 2017), and Taiwan at around 30. But 1050 and 29 are still relatively weak levels for both currencies—given the size of each countries’ surplus** there is ample scope for further appreciation. I consequently will be watching to see if the Treasury signals that it objects to the level where Korea and Taiwan are intervening even if the amount of intervention falls short of the formal criteria. Korea's intervention in November, December, and January was actually relatively heavy (the won weakened a bit in February, allowing Korea to sell some of its January purchases, but it looks likely that Korea intervened again to block appreciation through 1050 in late March/early April). And I am curious if the Treasury will show any sign that it is looking closely at shadow intervention—asking, for example, Korea to disclose the net foreign exchange position (including hedges) of its national pension service, and Taiwan to report not just the central bank’s forward book but also the aggregate foreign exchange position of its regulated insurers. There are also signs that Taiwan’s state banks may have been buying more foreign exchange than in the past. But there I am not holding my breath, I don’t really expect any changes.  Looming in the background is another issue. Without large-scale intervention, foreign demand for Treasuries may be a bit weaker than it has been in the past (see my magnus opus on how the U.S. finances its current account deficit). Deutsche Bank has highlighted this possibility in some of its recent research. They are in my view, more or less right to note that foreign demand for Treasuries historically has been a by-product of intervention, and often, the result of intervention well in excess of the current 2 percent of GDP threshold. But I am not sure that the Trump Administration is willing to declare that it wants to toss aside the Bennet criteria in order to encourage countries to maintain undervalued currencies so as to raise demand for Treasuries and thus facilitate foreign funding of the fiscal deficit.   *Taiwan though benefits from the bilateral balance criteria, as it exports its chips (semiconductors) to China, and thus the reported bilateral balance understates its "value-added" bilateral surplus. Taiwan's current account surplus rose in 2017 and is now bigger in dollar terms than Korea's surplus. ** The Setser/Frank estimates for reserve growth in the tables differ from the Treasury numbers in two ways: Cole Frank and I used the balance of payments data to estimate reserve growth, while the Treasury uses valuation-adjusted change in headline reserves, and I didn't deduct out estimated interest income. The Treasury believes that only actual purchases in the foreign exchange market should count, and tries to strip out interest income. For countries that already have too many reserves, I think the country should normally sell the interest income received on foreign bonds for domestic currency to cover payments on sterilization instruments and profit remittances back to the Finance Ministry. This matters for a country like Taiwan, which has about 80 percent of GDP in reserve assets. Interest income is likely over a percent of GDP, and will rise over time if U.S. rates continue to increase. I also included for reference changes in the government's holdings of portfolio debt. These purchases have often appeared in the balance of payments at times when Korea is intervening in the market: they look to be to be a form of shadow intervention.  
  • Southeast Asia
    Thailand’s Lessons for Democratic Regression: A Review of “Owners of the Map”
    It may be hard to believe now, as blustery generals run Thailand, the army busts up gatherings of political opponents, and junta rule—in one form or another—seems like it might never end, but the country was once touted as an example of democratization. I myself made this argument in the 1990s and early 2000s. The country had held multiple free elections and passed one of the most progressive constitutions in Asia. It had a vibrant press, and regularly witnessed massive public rallies led by civil society groups. I lived in Thailand from 1998 to 2001, and at that time society seemed to be overflowing with political discussions, arguments, and contested elections. I was hardly the only one to praise Thailand at the time. Freedom House rated Thailand as “Free” in their 2001 edition of Freedom in the World, their annual survey of each country in the world. (Thailand is now ranked “Not Free,” after having been ranked “Partly Free” for much of the 2000s and 2010s.) As I noted in a 2013 edited volume, Pathways to Freedom, many of the U.S. officials who traveled to the kingdom during this time lavished praise on its maturing democracy, an example of a place where the army had returned to the barracks for good. The reversal of Thailand’s democracy began in 2001 with the election of the populist leader Thaksin Shinawatra. Both during the campaign and as prime minister, he excelled at recognizing and manipulating public grievances. He preyed on working-class Thais’ legitimate feelings of economic injustice. He also, however, outlined a real policy platform to address injustices, and succeeded in instituting populist policy reforms, many of which benefitted Thai society. Unfortunately, some of these reforms were enacted at the expense of democratic norms and the rule of law. Then, when some middle-class and elite Thais realized that liberalism was being undermined, they took the wrong steps to fight back. There is a larger lesson to be learned from the trajectory of politics in Thailand. To gain power, Thaksin used political tactics very similar to those more recently adopted by leaders from Turkey and Hungary to the Philippines and, now, with the presidency of Donald Trump, the United States. Thaksin emerged after a period of austerity in Thailand, and like Law and Justice in Poland combined skillful pitting of rural voters against elites with effective economic policies. And like Rodrigo Duterte and many other modern-day populists, Thaksin identified dangerous “others” and targeted them, often while using these “others” to shore up his law-and-order credentials. Thaksin’s own anti-drug war in 2003—along with a broader war on “dark influences” that was popular with much of the public—utilized extra-judicial killings, and was eerily similar to Duterte’s current drug war. Thaksin also often highlighted his own wealth, positioning himself as the one man who could take measures to boost the economy, even if he did so without following democratic norms. This “I alone can fix it” style predated that of Narendra Modi, Duterte, and Trump. For more on how Thailand was “patient zero” in the global democratic regression, see my new review in the Washington Monthly.
  • Thailand
    Podcast: The Race for Strategic Alliances in Southeast Asia
    Podcast
    Situated in the heart of Southeast Asia, Thailand occupies a crucial geopolitical space in the region and is a major gateway to ASEAN markets. For years, it has maintained a balancing act between the U.S., its formal treaty ally, and China, its largest trading partner. But Thailand’s most recent coup—the 19th since 1932—has chilled the U.S.-Thai relationship, leaving Bangkok closer to Beijing. In his new book, Thailand: Shifting Ground Between the US and a Rising China, author Benjamin Zawacki argues that the United States needs to reexamine this critical alliance before it is usurped by a rising China. Listen to this week’s Asia Unbound podcast to hear why and how the United States should reinvigorate this important relationship. Listen on SoundCloud >>
  • Southeast Asia
    "Thailand: Shifting Ground Between the U.S. and a Rising China": A Review
    Over the past three years, as Thailand-United States relations soured following the May 2014 coup in Bangkok, many commentators argued that the Thai government was suddenly alienated from the United States and moving closer to China. Although the Obama administration had vowed to bolster diplomatic, strategic, and economic relations with Southeast Asian nations, as part of the pivot, or rebalance, after the coup it supposedly froze Thailand out, pushing Bangkok into the arms of Beijing. And, while the Donald J. Trump administration has made human rights a low priority in U.S. foreign policy, and hosted Prayuth for a visit in July 2017, the Trump administration’s distrust of diplomacy, gutting of the State Department, and “America First” themes have not generally played well in Southeast Asia. The reality was always more nuanced. Thailand did not suddenly break from the United States after the 2014 coup or upon Trump’s inauguration, and China did not suddenly gain massive new influence in the kingdom in the 2010s. More important, as Benjamin Zawacki reports in this timely new volume, the kingdom’s balancing act between giants actually goes back decades. Instead, Zawacki reports, Thailand, which has integrated ethnic Chinese better than most other Southeast Asian nations, and did not cut all links with Beijing even during the Cold War, has been moving toward China for over fifteen years; the U.S.-Thai relationship that existed in the 1960s and 1970s will never return. For more of my assessment of Zawacki’s important new book, see the full review in the Kyoto Review of Southeast Asia.
  • Thailand
    Thailand’s Junta Faces Mounting Pressure
    The ruling junta in Thailand, which seized power in May 2014, has repeatedly delayed holding elections. Most recently, after promising to hold an election in November of this year, junta leaders now have pushed back the election date to early 2019, after the military-installed interim parliamentary body extended the time of enforcement of an election bill. This change was supposedly intended to give political parties, who have been harshly repressed since May 2014, time to re-emerge and prepare for national elections. Still, with the junta having delayed elections multiple times before, this delay only further raises questions of whether the military might try to push off a vote later into 2019, or even further down the road. These delays not only give the army more time to rule directly, but potentially provide military leaders time to organize their own pro-military party, or coalition of parties, one of which may allow junta leader Prayuth Chan-ocha, who now calls himself a politician, to run in civilian politics. The delay also could allow the junta to create new ways to suppress Puea Thai, the dominant political party before the coup. (Prayuth recently told the U.S. Chairman of the Joint Chiefs of Staff that the election will be held in a “Thailand First” style.) Prayuth has even dangled the idea that the junta will simply remain in charge well into 2019 or beyond. Even as the Thai military delays elections, pressure is mounting on the junta in a variety of ways. Of course, since the May 2014 coup, the military has drastically altered the contours of Thai politics, in order to ensure that it remains extremely powerful even if an election is held and its favored party or coalition loses. It has increased the power of unelected and bureaucratic institutions, and created a long-term strategic plan for Thailand that will allow the military to influence politics for decades. But after several years of relative calm, due in large part to the fact that this is the most repressive junta in Thailand in decades, the military now faces a range of opposition movements that are speaking out more openly. Prominent civil society leaders and journalists have stepped up calls for General Prawit Wongsuwan, the number two in the junta, to step down from his position as deputy prime minister, after he was spotted in public wearing fancy wristwatches allegedly worth more than $1 million—assets he had never declared. Thai media outlets, like ThaiPBS, which have largely been deferential to the junta, have run polls publicly asking whether Thais think Prawit should resign—and getting a massive response indicating that he should. Meanwhile, other anti-government activists, and even some centrist politicians, have become bolder in recent months, perhaps showing the growing frustration with military rule. Leaders of the Democrat Party, the other major political party besides Puea Thai, have expressed growing frustration with the slow pace of movement toward an election. Prominent activists have launched a cross-country march to highlight public dislike of the government’s handling of many social issues, although the government has suppressed marchers and arrested some march leaders. Yet other activists have held small rallies in Bangkok and other cities to protest the junta and its election delays, despite the possibility that these rally leaders would all be arrested as well. Last weekend, several hundred protestors gathered in Bangkok to demand that the armed forces not delay the election. This opposition comes in the run-up to the (eventual) election, but it also comes in an environment in which the junta has, largely, not made good on its claims that, after seizing power, it would clean up politics. The Prawit watch saga, as well as multiple other stories about alleged graft by junta associates, has tarnished whatever plans the army had for combating graft. The junta’s anti-corruption campaign has, by and large, been limited to arrests and prosecutions of former members of Puea Thai, and their associates, on corruption charges. Meanwhile, Thailand’s economy is performing relatively strongly at the moment, but the junta’s policies have done little to expand growth prospects beyond Bangkok and the eastern corridor, where the military plans a massive investment program. The lack of stronger growth in the north and northeast could help Puea Thai at election time, a point Puea Thai leaders are apparently counting on, although the junta seems to recognize that it must spread growth more widely, and plans to raise the minimum wage and fund new anti-poverty programs. Still, if an election ever happens, the junta’s favored parties may be in a weaker position than the military expected only last year.
  • Southeast Asia
    Southeast Asia’s Press Freedoms Collapse: 2018 Could Be Worse for Southeast Asian Democracy Than 2017
    As I noted late last year, 2017 was a disastrous year for democracy in Southeast Asia. Democratic rights and freedoms already have been in decline in Southeast Asia for more than a decade, but 2017 was perhaps the worst year for the region in that decade. Cambodia’s semi-democratic system collapsed last year, the Philippines’ rule of law deteriorated, Myanmar witnessed ethnic cleansing, Thailand remained ruled by a military junta, and Indonesia faced rising populism and Islamism. Freedom House’s latest version of Freedom in the World, released today, in fact chronicles a global collapse in democracy, with global freedoms regressing for the 12th consecutive year, and democracy threatened nearly everywhere in the world. (I worked with Freedom House on some Asia chapters of Freedom in the World.) So far, however, in just the initial weeks of the year, 2018 is looking like it could be even worse for Southeast Asia. Most notably, press freedom is increasingly threatened across Southeast Asia. In some countries, like the Philippines, Cambodia, and Malaysia, even periods of authoritarian or semi-authoritarian rule did not in previous years halt the creation of powerful, independent news outlets. In fact, in Cambodia, independent news outlets and other civil society groups continued to operate, over the past two decades, even at times of severe repression by the Hun Sen government. But in recent months, even some of the most groundbreaking, independent news outlets in Southeast Asia have faced possible mortal peril, as increasingly autocratic rulers try to shut down media groups. Several of these Southeast Asian leaders, like Cambodian Prime Minister Hun Sen, have openly celebrated the U.S. administration’s war on “fake news,” and tried to associate their own crackdowns on the media with the White House’s approach to the press. The number of press outlets and reporters facing severe consequences is growing. In Thailand, the government has detained multiple reporters and increasingly just refuses to deal with the media—Prime Minister Prayuth Chan-ocha last week installed a cardboard facsimile of himself to “answer” media questions of the government. Last year, Hun Sen oversaw the shuttering of the Cambodia Daily and multiple independent radio outlets in Cambodia. The prime minister could well come after more news outlets in Cambodia this year, before national elections. At the end of last year, in a case similar to other cases brought against Myanmar journalists from local publications, the Myanmar authorities arrested two Reuters journalists, under the Official Secrets Act. Reuters noted that “The Ministry of Information has cited the police as saying they were ‘arrested for possessing important and secret government documents related to Rakhine State and security forces.’” The military and the civilian government in Myanmar have indeed become increasingly repressive in trying to crack down on reporting of events in Rakhine State, where a wave of ethnic cleansing has been going on. The two Reuters reporters allegedly had gotten documents showing a site in Rakhine State where a mass grave was located. The military has since admitted that there was a mass grave found in this village, but the two reporters are still under arrest. Now, last week another major blow was struck against Southeast Asian press freedom. Rappler, one of the most prominent independent news outlets in the Philippines—and one that has aggressively investigated the administration of President Rodrigo Duterte and been called “fake news” by the Philippine president—now faces government action that could force its closure. On Monday, Philippine officials confirmed that the Duterte government had revoked Rappler’s license to operate, although Rappler is appealing the decision. Duterte has in fact been at war with the press since he took office in 2016, and he has no love for Rappler. As the Guardian notes: In March [2017], Duterte described top newspaper Philippine Daily Inquirer and leading television broadcaster ABS-CBN as ‘sons of whores’ and warned them of karmic repercussions over their criticism of his drug war... Four months later, the Inquirer announced its owners were in talks to sell the publication. A business tycoon who backed Duterte’s 2016 election bid later disclosed he was planning to buy the Inquirer. Duterte in 2017 also threatened to block ABS-CBN’s application to renew its operating franchise, a permit that requires congressional approval. The ongoing war against the press in the Philippines, and the sale of the Daily Inquirer, has made Rappler even more central as an independent voice. But Rappler too may face so much pressure that it might close.
  • Thailand
    Thailand is Really, and I Mean Really, Close to Meeting the Treasury’s Manipulation Criteria
    The Treasury's April foreign exchange report should be interesting. Thailand hasn't been included in past foreign exchange reports.  Yet it is likely to meet all three of the criteria set out in the Bennet Amendment for a finding of "manipulation." 
  • Thailand
    A Follow-up on the Thai Baht
    Most countries intervene to limit appreciation, not directly to depreciate their currency. And limiting appreciation is a problem when the country has a large external surplus.
  • Thailand
    Thailand: Currency Manipulator?
    The Trump Administration seems to think of currency manipulation primarily as an issue with China. But “currency” actually is a much broader issue. Korea, Taiwan, and Singapore all have bigger current account surpluses, relative to their GDP, than China does. All have intervened to limit the appreciation of their currency within the past year. And all three have a long history of intervention, even if they intervened somewhat less when the dollar was exceptionally strong between the middle of 2014 and the middle of 2017. But the country that comes closest to meeting all three of the numerical criteria the Treasury now uses, following the Bennet amendment, to determine whether or not a country qualifies for “enhanced bilateral engagement” (what used to be called manipulation) is Thailand. Yep, Thailand. The three criteria are: Intervention (purchases, I assume) in the foreign exchange market in excess of two percent of GDP. A current account surplus in excess of 3 percent of GDP. A bilateral goods surplus with the U.S. of more than $20 billion dollars.* Thailand easily meets the first two criteria. Its current account surplus has soared after the baht’s depreciation in 2015, and now is close to 10 percent of Thailand’s GDP. 10 percent of GDP is a big number—it is higher than Germany or Korea right now. And roughly equal to China’s pre-crisis surplus at its peak. Thailand’s intervention in the foreign exchange market—including its intervention in the forward market—topped five percent of its GDP in the last twelve months of balance of payments data. Thailand’s reserves rose strongly in July and August, so there is no doubt Thailand continued to intervene throughout the third quarter. So it all comes down to the third criteria: a bilateral goods surplus with the U.S. in excess of $20 billion. And Thailand comes close. Very close. Its bilateral goods surplus in the last four quarters of U.S. data is above $19 billion… Changing the criteria to include services wouldn’t let Thailand off the hook. In 2015 Thailand ran a small bilateral services surplus with the U.S. (see table 2.2 or table 2.3 in the services trade data interactive tables; 2016 data isn’t yet available, the services data comes with a long lag and the bilateral data isn’t especially reliable). Remember the U.S. services surplus is mostly tourism—not anything more highfalutin (most services are still hard to deliver across borders and across time zones, and, well, our IPR giants tend to understate their intellectual property exports for tax reasons). And Thailand is also strong in tourism: the United States (like China) runs a bilateral tourism deficit with Thailand. Thailand historically hasn’t been covered in any detail in the foreign exchange report. It isn’t on the monitoring list in the last foreign exchange report. It hasn’t been “put on notice” so to speak. It should be. Based on current trends, Thailand’s bilateral surplus is likely to exceed the $20 billion threshold soon. Of course, there is an elephant in the room: Thailand’s 1997 crisis, and Thailand’s belief that the U.S. didn’t provide it with as much assistance back then as say it provided to Mexico.** But a crisis in the 1990s shouldn’t be a free pass twenty years later. Neither Thailand nor for that matter Korea should get “a get out of jail free” card now because of events twenty years ago. Thailand got into trouble in 1997 for a host of reasons: a credit-fueled real estate boom produced a large current account deficit, a lot of real estate companies took out a lot of foreign currency denominated debt even though they lacked foreign currency revenues, and the Thai banks and finance companies funded their domestic foreign currency lending with risky short-term borrowing. But it also fundamentally lacked enough reserves back then. Overall reserves weren’t high absolutely, and it turns out that Thailand had sold off a large fraction of its reserves in the forward market trying to defend the baht, so it really had almost zero in the bank. At the end of the second quarter of 1997, Thailand had about $30 billion in headline reserves, and had sold almost $30 billion forward. It literally had nothing in the bank. Thailand’s reserves, though, are way bigger now—absolutely, and relative to short-term external debt. Thailand has $180 billion plus in reserves, and has bought $30 billion in the forward market—so its reserves are higher than the headline number. Total reserves, counting forwards are about 50 percent of Thailand’s GDP—and its short-term debt is only a bit over 10 percent of its GDP. So while Thailand absolutely needed to rebuild its reserves and bring down its debt after its 1997 crisis, it subsequently has gone overboard—and is pretty clearly now intervening to hold its currency down, not because it needs more reserves to protect itself from another crisis. A current account surplus of 10 percent of GDP and reserves of close to 50 percent of GDP makes Thailand a small-scale version, numerically, of China back in 2007 or so.*** And, well, Thailand’s intervention does have an impact on the U.S. economy. Thailand is a big producer of auto parts and other manufactures these days, it isn’t primarily a commodity exporter.**** Perhaps some of the over $3 billion in imports of telecommunications equipment, the $3 billion in imports of auto parts (including tires) from Thailand and $0.75 billion in imports of household appliances just squeezes out other imports—but competition from places like Thailand also adds pressure on other countries to keep their exchange rates artificially depressed. It all adds up. One last point: designating a country for “enhanced bilateral engagement” doesn’t lead automatically to meaningful sanctions, let alone a trade war. The sanctions outlined in the Bennet amendment are quite mild. But it would force a dialogue. And, well, if the Bennet sanctions are too mild for the Trump Administration’s taste, they could always experiment with counter-intervention.   * I am not a huge fan of the bilateral balance criteria. For one, I think it lets the NIEs (Hong Kong, South Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan) off the hook a bit too easily, as they export parts to China and thus account for a portion of China’s surplus! But more generally, there is no particular reason to think a bilateral surplus with the U.S. on its own signals an unhealthy overall pattern of trade. But in Thailand’s current case, its bilateral surplus with the U.S. is a component of its overall surplus, and the overall surplus is clearly quite large. ** Thailand did not get a bilateral credit line from the Treasury’s Exchange Stabilization Fund back in 1997, in part because of the restrictions that Congress placed on its use after Mexico. But I think the reality is that the use of the Exchange Stabilization Fund is the exception not the rule–Mexico was treated a bit differently because it is on the U.S. border, but also because it really did primarily have a short-term liquidity problem and thus was in a position to repay the Treasury quite rapidly. *** The combined current account surplus of the NIEs, Malaysia, and Thailand in 2016 was around $300 billion– substantially larger than China’s $200 billion surplus in 2016. Malaysia is the only one of these six that hasn’t been intervening this year to limit appreciation. **** Thailand’s commodity exports are actually down a bit: the U.S. is importing less Thai seafood these days, and the U.S. is no longer importing oil from Thailand (a few years back the U.S. was importing half a billion in oil from Thailand–there are often surprises hidden in the bilateral numbers).
  • Thailand
    With Yingluck Gone, What Now for Thai Politics?
    Throughout this past summer, Thai politicians, journalists, and other opinion leaders waited anxiously for the conclusion of the trial of former Prime Minister Yingluck Shinawatra, who was removed by a military coup in May 2014. Yingluck had been brought up on charges that she mismanaged a rice subsidy scheme that wound up losing some $8 billion; the junta government claimed that her mismanagement also had allowed vast corruption in the subsidy program. The charges were somewhat unusual, since she was not personally accused of corruption in the program. In some ways, she was being charged with making bad decisions in government, which is not normally considered a crime. But, a central objective of the junta government has been to eradicate the influence of the Shinawatra family in Thai politics, and to break the bond between the Shinawatras and their mass of mostly rural supporters. The charges appeared, in part, like one way to crush Yingluck and her allies. Yingluck ultimately did not show up to hear her verdict on August 25, disappointing crowds of backers at the court, and she is believed to have fled Thailand. Will her flight destroy the Shinawatra family’s power, and further entrench the junta and its favored politicians? For more on the Yingluck case and Thai politics, see my new World Politics Review column.
  • Thailand
    Thailand’s Enforced Calm Could Collapse After Yingluck Trial
    On Friday, former Thai Prime Minister Yingluck Shinawatra will hear the verdict in her trial over allegedly neglecting management of a massive rice subsidy plan. She oversaw the rice subsidy during her government, which was deposed by the Thai military in 2014. The verdict could trigger new unrest in Thailand, which has been relatively calm for the past year. Yingluck, the younger sister of former Prime Minister Thaksin Shinawatra, is the most visible symbol of the Thaksinite Puea Thai party who still remains in Thailand. (Thaksin lives in exile, and no other Puea Thai leader has the name recognition of Yingluck.) Since the 2014 coup, Yingluck has been living a very curtailed life, but she has managed to remain in the public eye. She has done so by welcoming supporters at her house for nonpolitical gatherings that were then shared on social media, continuing to speak to the public via social media and her trial statements, and generally serving as a rallying point for Puea Thai supporters in the midst of three-plus years of military rule. Over the past year, the military has continued its campaign to crush dissent, but at the same time a veneer of calm has descended over Thailand—and not only because of the harsh repression. To be sure, the junta continues to severely restrict freedoms, going far beyond the actions of Thai military leaders in recent decades. Most recently, the authorities this month announced charges against a group of participants in a major academic conference in Chiang Mai, claiming that they violated a prohibition on public assembly. Their crime? New Mandala reported that it consisted of: “put[ting] up signs reading ‘This is an academic forum, not a military camp’ on the wall of a seminar room of the Chiang Mai International Exhibition and Convention Center during the Thai Studies conference, and [taking] photos with the signs.” Yet at the same time, the death of King Bhumibhol last year, the period of post-Bhumibhol mourning, the passage of a new constitution in 2016, and the expectations of elections in 2018 have combined to tamp down antigovernment sentiment. Opponents of the junta may hope that the military will finally give way in 2018, although the timeline for an actual election remains uncertain. Still, some Puea Thai figures may believe that encouraging large-scale protest is not wise at this time, given that the party seems poised to win any upcoming election. As Shawn Crispin has noted in Asia Times, the government’s own internal polls have shown that Puea Thai would likely win the most seats in the lower house of Parliament, though the new constitution is designed to make it very difficult for any party, including Puea Thai, to win a majority. Still, it is not out of the question that Puea Thai could perform so well, even in the new system created by the 2016 constitution, that it could win an absolute majority. A verdict that sends Yingluck to jail—rather than a not guilty verdict or a guilty verdict with some kind of suspended sentence—could actually help push Puea Thai toward that majority. A guilty verdict with jail time could lead to renewed public protests in Bangkok and the north and northeast, the heartland of Puea Thai backers. Even in the current climate of intense repression, the party’s core supporters have been active. Puea Thai backers have organized outside the Yingluck courthouse, and the junta has taken extensive preparations for larger unrest after the court’s decision. The junta has even threatened anyone who drives Yingluck supporters to the court. It also has reportedly mobilized thousands of police men and women to stand guard outside the trial venue. Indeed, a guilty verdict and jail time, issued in a country under military rule and for a charge that seems like a political prosecution to many Puea Thai supporters, would probably make Yingluck an even more sympathetic public figure. A not guilty verdict, meanwhile, would anger core junta backers and perhaps the top generals themselves; in the minds of the junta’s pro-military/royalist supporters, a not guilty verdict might make the junta look weak. As The Nation reported, the junta seems to understand the possibility of Yingluck looking like a martyr, noting that the military hoped that the former prime minister would flee the country rather than face the verdict. The junta’s desire not to see Yingluck made into a martyr may result in the court choosing a middle ground verdict, like finding Yingluck guilty but suspending her sentence. Such a middle path might keep the uneasy peace in Thailand that has existed since the king’s death last year, but the peace cannot hold indefinitely. The junta cannot postpone an election forever, and its favored parties will have difficulty defending the army’s record during its three-plus years running Thailand. The country’s economy has continued to stagnate, and decisions on infrastructure, the education system, and other important issues have remained deadlocked. The Yingluck trial has not proven a rally point for the junta, which is why the military may have wanted the former prime minister to simply leave the country.