International Monetary Fund (IMF)

  • Eurozone
    Germany Cannot Quit Fiscal Consolidation
    Fiscally Driven Rebalancing Turns Out to Be Hard
  • Trade
    Using Fiscal Policy to Drive Trade Rebalancing Turns Out To Be Hard
    The idea behind “fiscally-driven external rebalancing” is straightforward. If countries with external (e.g. trade) surpluses run expansionary fiscal policies, they will raise their own level of demand and increase their imports. More expansionary fiscal policies would generally lead to tighter monetary policies, which also would raise the value of their currencies. And if countries with external (trade) deficits run tighter fiscal policy, they will restrain their own demand growth and thus limit imports. Firms in the countries with tighter fiscal policies and less demand will start to look to export to countries with looser fiscal policies and more demand. This logic fits well with IMF orthodoxy: the IMF generally finds that fiscal policy has a significant impact on the external balance, unlike trade policy.* But it often encounters opposition, as it implies that the fiscal policy that is right for one country can be wrong for another. Many Germans, for example, think they need to run fiscal surpluses to set a good example for their neighbors. Yet the logic of using fiscal policy to drive external trade adjustment runs in the opposite direction. To bring its trade surplus down, Germany would need to run a looser fiscal policy. The positive impact of such policies on demand in Germany (and other the surplus countries) would spillover to the global economy and allow countries with external deficits to tighten their fiscal policies without creating a broader shortfall of demand that slows growth. So one implication of using fiscal policy to drive trade rebalancing is that there is no single fiscal policy target (or fiscal policy direction) that works for all countries. Budget balance for example isn’t always the right goal of national fiscal policy. Some countries need to run fiscal deficits to help bring their external surpluses down. That idea certainly encounters resistance. And as practical matter, the IMF’s latest estimates show that Europe hasn’t used fiscal policy to help facilitate its own internal adjustment.** The big external surpluses in the eurozone are in the Netherlands and Germany. Germany and the Netherlands also have a lot of fiscal space thanks to relatively low levels of public debt, and could safely run expansionary fiscal policies without calling their own fiscal solvency into question. And the countries with lots of external debt and limited fiscal space tend to be further to the south: Italy and Spain for example (I am over generalizing a bit here—Spain has more external debt than Italy and a bigger fiscal deficit, while Italy has a bigger public debt stock and less growth).*** The eurozone also runs a significant overall external surplus, has internal economic slack and has low interest rates—it could help bring global trade into better balance (and raise the global return on saving) with a more expansionary overall fiscal policy while also bringing its own economy closer to full employment. Win-win, at least in theory. In practice, though, the eurozone didn’t run an expansionary overall fiscal policy last year. The change in the structural fiscal balance was positive, but only just.*** And the fiscal contraction in Europe last year came from the external surplus countries: the Netherlands notably. Not from the former external deficit countries. Fiscal expansions in Italy and Spain provided the offset that prevented the consolidation in the Netherlands from giving rise to an overall consolidation in the eurozone. The pattern of fiscal consolidation in the eurozone is a bit different than what the IMF recommended. The IMF wanted fiscal expansion in the Netherlands, and fiscal consolidation in Spain, Italy, and others (generally at a pace of about 0.5 percent of GDP a year)—more or less the opposite of what happened. And what of Germany? Well, the IMF thought a year ago that Germany was doing a fiscal expansion—one that would bring its fiscal surplus down from about one percent of GDP (see paragraph 9 of the staff report, and the table on German general government operations on p. 8). But it turns out there wasn’t much of a structural fiscal expansion in Germany last year. The structural fiscal balance stayed in a substantial surplus. That’s the problem. It turns out surplus countries seem to like surpluses. They often aren’t willing to take policy action to expand demand. And the since the output of the eurozone's traditional deficit countries is generally constrained by weak demand, they tend to want to run more expansionary policies to boost their economies. The same basic point applies globally. For fiscal policy to drive global demand rebalancing, the external surplus countries around the world need to run more expansionary policies. That means the eurozone, Korea, and Japan, among others, should adapt more expansionary policies (along with Sweden, Switzerland, and Singapore). And of course the U.S. would need to adopt a more contractionary fiscal policy, one aimed at bringing the U.S. current account deficit down. But there isn’t much sign in the IMF’s data for 2016 that the surplus countries are willing to do meaningful fiscal expansions (and as I noted last year, in many cases the IMF hasn’t been willing to advocate fiscal expansions in its fiscal advice to major surplus countries). Korea’s structural surplus remains big (the IMF looks at a measure of the fiscal balance that includes the surplus in Korea’s social security system, which offsets the headline deficit) and didn’t change much in 2016. The latest WEO data suggests a (very) modest structural fiscal tightening in 2016, with more tightening in 2017. Japan has an ongoing structural fiscal deficit—its current account surplus comes from high corporate savings, not a tight fiscal policy. It has slowed the pace of consolidation from 2014 (thankfully) but its structural balance does't suggest that is doing much to support demand. It continues to rely heavily on net exports to support its growth. And, as for the United States…well, the President wants a big deficit-funded tax cut. **** *The IMF recognized in its 2016 external sector report that fiscal policy should play a role supporting balance of payments adjustment in many (but not all) “surplus” economies. See paragraph 28: “Countries facing stronger-than-warranted external positions and negative output gaps should primarily rely on fiscal policy to help close both domestic and external gaps, although the stimulus should be geared to support structural reform objectives. However, reliance on fiscal support depends very much on the availability of buffers. Korea, Sweden, Thailand, and the Netherlands appear to have room to ease in relative terms. Other countries, like Japan, where current fiscal space is more limited, will need to coordinate carefully the use of monetary and fiscal space with structural and income policies. Meanwhile, in the few cases where positive external gaps are paired with near zero or positive output gaps (Malaysia, Germany), monetary policy, if available as an independent instrument, should play a larger role (Malaysia). Those economies without independent monetary policy but with fiscal policy space (Germany), should use that space to finance growth-friendly policies that would support external rebalancing (including through an internal appreciation) with only a temporary and limited effect on the output gap." ** For the charts, Cole Frank and I used changes in the cyclically adjusted structural fiscal balance, as reported in the the IMF's latest WEO data base. There is an argument that the structural fiscal balance isn't the right measure, as interest expenditure has fallen (though you can debate this—interest paid domestically should support some spending), and the right measures for the fiscal impulse is the change in the cyclically adjusted primary fiscal balance. The IMF doesn't report that though (it reports the primary balance, but not the cyclically adjusted primary balance). Eyeballing the numbers, though, doesn't suggest this matters much, with the potential exception of Japan (where the debt really is held domestically). For Spain in 2012, I did use the change in the cyclically adjusted IMF primary balance as reported in the 2014 IMF article IV—as the structural balance includes the bank recapitalization bill (the "official" number implied a consolidation of around 4 percent of GDP). More generally, it should be noted these numbers are estimates, not the word of god. The 2016 numbers likely will be revised. *** Some additional throat clearing. The eurozone used to have an internal version of the world’s balance of payments imbalances. Some countries ran big surpluses, others ran big deficits. By and large, those deficits have disappeared, while the surpluses stayed big—hence the rise in the eurozone's surplus with the world. But the large deficits left behind a large stock of external debt (notably in Greece, Portugal, and Spain), and the fall in the deficit left many parts of the eurozone short demand. So an imbalances problem inside the eurozone turned into a demand problem inside Europe, and, without the deficits in the “south” the eurozone started running large external surpluses and exporting its savings to the world. **** U.S. Treasury Secretary Mnuchin has embraced the argument that fiscal reflation in the surplus countries can help address global balance of payments imbalances. I agree. But it is kind of hard to square that argument with the Trump Administration’s deficit raising tax proposals.
  • Monetary Policy
    The Combined Surplus of Asia and Europe Stayed Big in 2016
    A long time ago I confessed that I like to read the IMF’s World Economic Outlook (WEO) from back to front. OK, I sometimes skip a few chapters. But I take particular interest in the IMF’s data tables (the World Economic Outlook electronic data set is also very well done, though sadly a bit lacking in balance of payments data).* And the data tables show the combined current account surplus of Europe and the manufacturing heavy parts of Asia—a surplus that reflects Asia's excess savings and Europe's relatively weak investment—remained quite big in 2016. China's surplus dropped a bit in 2016, but that didn't really bring down the total surplus of the major Asian manufacturing exporters. Much of the fall in China’s surplus was offset by a rise in Japan’s surplus. The WEO data tables suggest that net exports accounted for about half of Japan's 1 percent 2016 growth—Japan isn't yet growing primarily on the basis of an expansion of internal demand. And the combined surplus of Korea, Taiwan, Singapore and Hong Kong remains far larger than it was before the global financial crisis in 2008. The Asian NIEs (South Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore) collectively now run a bigger surplus than China. As a result, in dollar terms—and also relative to the GDP of Asia’s trading partners—"manufacturing" Asia's combined surplus hasn’t come down that much over the last ten years. The size of the combined surplus of Europe and “manufacturing” Asia necessarily means that other large parts of the global economy need to run large deficits in manufactured goods. To be sure, barring an energy revolution, the big oil and gas exporters will necessarily trade oil for manufactured goods (and holidays), and parts of Asia and Europe equally will need to trade manufactures for energy. But the big Asian and European manufacturing exporters could not maintain surpluses of their current scale in the absence of a U.S. trade deficit in manufacturing that is as large as it was back in 2005 or 2006. There are only so many ways the global balance of payments can add up. While the surplus of key parts of the global economy haven't moved much, the nature of the financial outflows that channel the current account surplus of Europe and Asia (their savings surplus so speak) to the rest of the world has certainly changed. Setting a few countries (Switzerland, and perhaps Singapore***) aside, governments aren’t directly channeling funds abroad through the build-up of their reserves and the assets of their sovereign funds. Here is a plot of the growth in Asia’s official assets. My measure of official asset growth is mostly reported reserve growth, but is has been adjusted to include changes in countries' disclosed forward position and China's "other foreign assets." I also added in the rise in the non-reserve portfolio holdings held by the public sector (and I assumed China's portfolio outflows are from government institutions). This is a way of capturing sovereign wealth fund and public pension fund outflows. I did not add in the external lending of China's state banks. To be honest these adjustments are primarily for my own satisfaction (they all come from the balance of payments data—I am trying to avoid valuation adjustment these days). Looking only at reserves (adjusted for forwards and China's other foreign assets) would not materially change the picture. And here is the similar plot for Europe looking only at reserves (I didn’t include Norway—too much of an oil-exporter—so I didn’t really need to adjust for official non-reserve assets). And here is a chart adding the reserve growth of the major oil exporting regions to Asian official asset growth.*** It clearly shows that the growth in official assets was correlated with the big run-up in their combined surplus prior to the crisis (for much more, see Joe Gagnon's 2013 working paper, and his forthcoming book with Fred Bergsten) and that the countries that historically have accounted for most of the reserve build-up are now running down their stock of assets. Broadly speaking, over the last ten years, Asia's surplus hasn't changed much while Europe has replaced the oil exporters as the second main driver of global payments imbalances. And private outflows rather than official outflows have become the financial counterpart to the world's big current account surpluses. That in turn matters for the composition of inflows into the United States: the world is buying fewer Treasuries and far more U.S. corporate bonds—though Asia also seems to have regained confidence in Freddie and Fannie. Taiwanese life insurers, Korean pension funds, and Japanese banks have more risk tolerance than traditional central bank reserve managers. The same is true of German insurers, Dutch pension funds, and for that matter Switzerland's reserve managers—who have more freedom than most of their counterparts to buy equities and corporate bonds alongside traditional reserve assets. Such changes in the composition of inflows to the U.S. could help explain why the IMF found that relative to fundamentals, U.S. corporate spreads seem a bit tight… One last point: The U.S. Treasury suspects that this fall off in reserve growth is largely a function of the dollar's strength, and has expressed concern that it may not be durable in its most recent foreign exchange report. I generally agree: the world's central banks historically have intervened far more when the dollar is weak than when the dollar is strong. The major surplus countries in a sense only need to step up and the use their government balance sheets when the market doesn't want to fund the U.S. external deficit. But I also suspect the world's big surplus countries are also now a bit more skilled than in the past at disguising their intervention—sovereign wealth funds can keep foreign assets off the books of the central bank, government pension funds often do some of the heavy lifting, and, in China's case, the growth in the overseas lending of China's state banks is likely to have structurally reduced the pace of reserve growth in good times. When intervention returns, it may not be primarily through the use of central bank balance sheets. *The long-standing joke that the IMF stands for “It is mostly fiscal” applies to the WEO data set. Tons of fiscal numbers. And for the balance of payments, only the current account (at least for individual countries). Sad! ** The overall U.S. external deficit is of course smaller, thanks mostly to a large fall in the oil deficit. The rise in the offshore income of U.S. multinationals also helped, as did the fall in the rate the U.S. paid on its external borrowing. *** I was lazy and did not try to adjust for the buildup of sovereign wealth fund assets in the Middle East. I have another technical complaint here. The IMF used to provide an estimate of official outflows from the Middle East and North Africa, which was a good proxy for the activity of the region's sovereign wealth funds—it was one of the bits of the WEO data tables that I found most useful. With the shift to the new IMF balance of payments standard (BPM 6) the IMF now only reports aggregated portfolio outflows. The old breakdown was in some ways more useful. The IMF could help to address this by insisting that more countries report the disaggregated data on portfolio outflows—even when this shows that the public sector accounts for the bulk of outflows. **** Singapore's headline reserves aren’t moving, but Singapore’s forward book is now rising and government deposits abroad have soared—call me suspicious.
  • Greece
    Global Economics Monthly: March 2017
    Bottom Line: Greece and its creditors are again locked in a showdown over reforms, cash, and debt relief. Another cliff-hanger ahead of heavy July debt payments looks likely. Extend-and-pretend is a dead end for Greece and an increasingly populist Europe, and a more ambitious agreement seems ruled out by bailout fatigue in creditor countries. Markets are once again underestimating the risks of “Grexit.” The Greek government’s negotiations with Europe and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) once again occupy the front page of the papers, and all parties appear to have learned little from past exercises. Ahead of a March 20 meeting of Eurogroup finance ministers, Greece is resisting reforms to pensions, labor and product markets, and fiscal policy that would unlock the next tranche of assistance and pave the way for negotiations on debt relief at some unspecified future date (certainly after German elections). Creditors are resisting a concrete commitment to debt relief that could mobilize support in Greece for reforms, while the IMF is criticizing both sides and threatening to withhold its endorsement (and financial support) of any deal. Most likely, the standoff will continue until July, when $8 billion in debt payments is due to the European Central Bank, the IMF, and private creditors (see figure 1). Greece appears to have neither the will nor the resources to make those payments, so avoiding default will require European creditors to disburse from their existing loan programs. FIGURE 1. GREEK DEBT REDEMPTION SCHEDULE IN 2017 The expectation that, as in the past, Greece and its creditors will reach a deal at the last minute has provided support to markets. Most investors I talked to also assume that the IMF will soften its opposition to a kick-the-can deal and agree to come along in some form. But short-term agreements to provide more cash for incremental reforms—while deferring concrete decisions on debt—mean that a durable solution to the Greek crisis is becoming more remote. From the start of the Greek drama in 2010, successive Greek governments have prioritized fiscal adjustment while deferring the fundamental structural reforms to the economy that would allow Greece to be competitive in the eurozone over the long term. As a consequence, growth remains anemic (even by the standards of an underperforming eurozone), unemployment is sky high, support for continued adjustment is collapsing, and Prime Minister Alexis Tsipras’s governing majority is shrinking. Recognizing his diminished room to maneuver, Tspiras has hardened his resistance to additional austerity. The deal investors expect is not a deal for Greek growth. THIS TIME IS DIFFERENT Although there will be a strong hint of déjà vu to this story for most readers, there are a few elements different from past negotiations. The first is that the IMF has taken a much firmer stance against the current program, and its fire has been aimed at both the creditors and the debtor. The IMF has been sharply critical of Greece’s structural reform effort, including the country’s reliance on temporary tax measures, a continued massive pension deficit, and its desire to roll back earlier reforms to collective bargaining. But the IMF has also attacked European creditor governments for unrealistic program assumptions and not committing to long-term debt relief. This stance between the two sides—on the one hand attacking the ambitious fiscal targets proposed by creditors as unrealistically austere and unlikely to be achieved, and on the other hand pointing out that more realistic fiscal targets will produce unsustainable levels of debt—has made IMF enemies all around. And, in contrast to past negotiations, the IMF appears to be quite dug in this time. The second new element is the rising populist backlash against continued bailouts in the European Union (EU). I have argued in the past that the primary risk to European economic policymaking may not be the risk of anti-EU parties coming to power but how those rising nationalistic pressures constrain policymaking across Europe and make an agreement among the major countries (much less unanimous agreement across all members of the eurozone) increasing difficult. Such is the case here. Notably, it is extraordinarily difficult for a Dutch or German policymaker, pressured by anti-immigration and anti-EU sentiments at home during an election period, to make precedent-setting concessions to Greece on debt. Those same election pressures create incentives to avoid the chaos that would accompany Grexit, but they also limit the capacity to agree on innovative solutions that would provide hope to Greeks. Late last year, I was convinced that a breakthrough was possible. Greece would commit to additional reforms and European creditors would provide a long-term commitment by capping interest payments. This guarantee would be provided by the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) and would represent a transfer of resources to Greece. Specifically, if interest rates remained low the guarantee would not come into play, but if rates rose the ESM would cover the difference between the cost of funding Greece and the capped rate. Viewed from the perspective of today’s markets, this would be a backdoor fiscal transfer from creditor countries to Greece in expected value terms, which would give the IMF (and hopefully markets) confidence that Greece’s debt profile would remain sustainable. I still see merit in such an approach, but against the backdrop of Europe’s challenges, the odds of reaching an agreement during the current electoral cycle seem increasingly remote. The public summary from the IMF board’s most recent meeting on Greece showed unusual candor regarding the extent of disagreement among major countries. Reading through the IMF’s coded language, it is clear that the U.S. government and many others back the IMF’s tough line on the negotiations, which has angered European governments. For the U.S. government in particular, this represents a sharp break from the Barack Obama administration, which pushed for continued IMF involvement. It is unclear at this point whether the change reflects the views of the Donald J. Trump administration, but I would not be surprised if, once the new team is fully in place, the United States takes a tougher stance against large but weak IMF programs. If the IMF is serious in its new firm line on Greece, it may find a strong ally in the Trump administration. CONCLUSION All of this suggests that, for economic and political reasons, the window may be closing on a comprehensive resolution of Greece’s crisis. I would not bet against a deal to buy time, though probably without the involvement of the IMF. With each showdown, the risk increases that the Greek government will decide that its economic future is better outside the eurozone. Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon BREXIT UK Prime Minister Theresa May’s government still plans to trigger Article 50 before the end of March. But the invocation will likely not occur until late March, and formal talks with the EU will not start until mid-May, further exacerbating the uncertainty of the Brexit process. FRENCH PRESIDENTIAL ELECTION While recent polls suggest Francois Fillon or Emmanuel Macron to be elected in the incoming French election, a surprise victory of Marine Le Pen remains a risk. CHINA The Chinese government has lowered the annual growth target to around 6.5 percent. The shift of focus to containing the risks of high leverage to financial stability is important. However, more tangible results of economic liberalization, such as reforming state-owned enterprises, are necessary to sustain the growth momentum.
  • China
    China: Too Much Investment, But Also Way Too Much Savings
    Most analysis of China’s economy emphasizes the risks posed by China’s high level of investment, and the associated rise in corporate debt. Investment is an unusually large share of China’s economy. That high level of investment is sustained by a very rapid growth in credit, and an ever-growing stock of internal debt. Corporate borrowing in particular has increased relative to GDP. Not all this investment will generate a positive return, leaving legacy losses that someone will have to bear. Rapid credit growth has been a fairly reliable indicator of banking trouble. China is unlikely to be different. Concern about the excesses from China’s investment boom permeate the IMF’s latest assessment of China, loom large in the BIS’s work, and the blogosphere. Gabriel Wildau of the Financial Times: "Global watchdogs including the International Monetary Fund and the Bank for International Settlements (not to mention this blog) have become increasingly shrill in their warnings that China’s rising debt load poses global risks." Yet I have to confess that defining China’s primary macroeconomic challenge entirely as "too much debt financing too much investment" makes me a bit uncomfortable. Investment is a component of aggregate demand. Arguing that China invests too much comes close to implying that, as a result of its credit boom/ bubble, China is providing too much demand to its own economy, and, as a result, too much demand for the global economy. That doesn’t seem entirely right. China’s banks have not needed to borrow from the rest of the world to support the rapid growth of domestic credit. China’s enormous loan growth, counting the growth in shadow lending, has been self-financed; deposits and shadow deposits seem to exceed loans and shadow loans.* Most countries in the midst of credit booms run sizable external deficits. China, by contrast, still runs a meaningful current account surplus. China is exporting savings even as it invests close to 45 percent of its GDP. And even with an extraordinary high level of domestic investment, China’s economy still, on net, relies on demand from the rest of the world to operate at full capacity. That is what differentiates China from most countries that experience a credit and investment boom. An alternative frame would start with the argument that China saves too much. A high level of national savings—national savings has been close to 50 percent of GDP for the last ten years, and was 48 percent of GDP in 2015, according to the IMF (WEO data)—creates an on-going risk that China will either over-supply savings to its own economy, leading to domestic excesses, or to the world, adding to the risks from global payments imbalances. From this point of view, the high level of investment, and the risks that come from high levels of investment, flow in part from the set of policies that have given rise to extraordinarily high levels of domestic savings. After the global financial crisis, the vast bulk of Chinese savings now is invested, no doubt rather inefficiently, at home. Bai, Hsieh, and Song’s excellent Brookings Paper on Economic Activity emphasizes that the surge in investment after the crisis was very much a product of government policy. But even with a high level of investment spurred by rapid growth in domestic credit some Chinese savings still bleeds out into the world economy. And China’s savings exports—exporting savings is an alternative way of describing a current account surplus—create difficulties when most advanced economies themselves are struggling with too much savings of their own, and have trouble putting all the savings now available in their economies to good use. That is what low global interest rates and weak global demand growth are telling us. Thus, from the rest of the world’s point of view, a fall in investment in China on its own poses a set of risks. Less investment means less demand for imports. The imported component of investment is, for now, much higher than the imported component of consumption. China’s recent import growth has been quite weak. It is increasingly clear that the slowdown in Chinese investment in 2014 and 2015 had a larger global impact—counting the second-order impact on commodity prices and investment in commodity production—than was initially expected.** If less investment leads to a shortfall in growth in China and monetary easing, it would also tend to push China’s exchange rate down—resulting in the risk that China would both import less and export more. That isn’t good for a world short on demand and short on growth. From the point of view of the rest of the world, the “win” stems from a fall in Chinese savings, not a fall in investment. Lower savings would mean China could invest less at home without the need to export savings to the rest of the world. Lower savings implies higher levels of consumption, whether private or public, and more domestic demand. Lower savings would tend to put upward pressure on interest rates, and thus reduce demand for credit. Higher interest rates would tend to discourage capital outflows and support China’s exchange rate. That’s all good for China and good for the world. It would result in lower domestic risks and lower external risks. So I worry a bit when policy advice for China focuses primarily on reducing investment, without an equal emphasis on the policies to reduce Chinese savings. To take one example, the IMF’s last Article IV focused heavily on the need to slow credit growth and reduce the amount of funding available for investment, and argued that China should not juice credit to meet an artificial growth target. I agree with both pieces of the IMF’s advice. But I also am not sure that it is enough to just slow credit. I would have liked to see a parallel emphasis on a set of policies that would help to lower China’s high national saving rate. The IMF’s long-run forecast assumes that China’s demographics—and the policy changes already in train (a half point projected increase in public health spending, for example)—will be enough to bring down China’s savings (as a share of GDP) at a faster clip than Chinese investment falls (as a share of GDP); see paragraph 25 of this paper. Even as the off-balance sheet deficit falls and the on-budget fiscal deficit remains roughly constant.*** Mechanically, that is how the IMF can forecast a fall in the current account deficit alongside a fall in investment and a fall in China’s augmented fiscal deficit. So the IMF’s external forecast in effect makes a big bet on the argument that Chinese savings is poised to fall significantly even without major new policy reforms in China. The actual fall in savings from 2011 to 2015 was rather modest, so the IMF is projecting a bit of a change. The BIS also has long emphasized the risks from China’s rapid credit growth. Fair enough: the BIS has a mandate that focuses on financial stability, and there is no doubt that China’s very rapid pace of credit growth is adding to range of domestic financial fragilities. To my knowledge, though, the BIS hasn’t warned that in a high savings economy, slower credit growth without parallel reforms to reduce the savings rate runs a substantial risk of leading to a rise in savings exports, and a return to large current account surpluses. From 2005 to 2007, China held credit growth down through a host of policies—high reserve requirements and tight lending curbs on the formal banking system, and limited tolerance of shadow finance. The result? Fewer domestic risks no doubt. But also a policy constellation that led to 10 percent of GDP current account surpluses in China.**** Those surpluses, and the offsetting current account deficits in places like the U.S. and Spain, weren’t healthy for the global economy. Do not get me wrong. It would be far healthier for China if it didn’t need to rely so heavily on rapid credit growth to keep investment and demand up. China’s banks already have a ton of bad loans and many almost certainly need a substantial capital injection. More lending likely means more bad loans. The risks here are real. But I also would be more comfortable if the global policy agenda put somewhat more focus on the risks from high Chinese savings—as in China’s case, high domestic savings are a root cause of a lot of the domestic excesses. I am not convinced that China’s national savings rate will head down on its own, without any policy help. * See, among others, Tao Wang of UBS—who has pulled together the relevant data in her market research. ** Both the IMF and the ECB have argued that the fall in investment explains much of its recent weakness in Chinese import growth, and thus help explain the recent weakness in global trade. The IMF and ECB papers build on work first done by Bussiere, Callegari, Ghironi, Sestieri, and Yamano. Both Chapter 2 (on trade) and Chapter 4 (on spillovers from China) of the most recent WEO imply that the 2014-15 investment slowdown had larger than initially expected global spillover. *** A technical point. A large government deficit usually lowers national savings. So from a savings and investment point of view, a traditional government deficit tends to impact the current account by lowering savings. But it seems like much of the augmented fiscal deficit—the IMF’s term for the borrowing of local government investment vehicles and the like that doesn’t show up in formal definitions of even the “general government” fiscal deficit—has shown up as a rise in investment. The IMF’s adjustment thus implies private investment (and private credit growth) has been overstated a bit, and public investment understated. So if Bai, Hsieh, and Song are right, a fall in the augmented part of the augmented fiscal deficit would show up as a fall in investment, not a fall in national savings. The line between the state and firms is especially blurry in China, as many firms are owned by the state—but expanding the perimeter of “fiscal policy” to include various local financing vehicles that could be viewed as state enterprises requires some offsetting adjustments. **** The BIS "credit gap" (data here, and here) was negative when China’s current account surplus was at its peak; that isn’t an accident. China was suppressing lending growth through loan quotas and high bank reserve requirements at the time.
  • Japan
    The IMF’s Recommended Fiscal Path For Japan
    With a bit of technical assistance, I was able to do a better job of quantifying the IMF’s recommended fiscal path for Japan. The IMF wants a 50 to 100 basis point rise in Japan’s consumption tax every year for the foreseeable future, starting in 2017. A 50 basis point rise would result in between 20 and 25 basis points of GDP in structural fiscal consolidation a year (the call for the tax increase is in paragraph 23 of the staff report, and is echoed in the IMF’s working paper). The IMF doesn’t want Japan to continue relying on fiscal stimulus packages, which typically have funds for public investment and the like (paragraph 23). As a result, there is a 60 basis points of GDP consolidation from the roll-off of past stimulus packages (the change in the structural primary balance is in both table 1 on p.38 table 4 on p.41 of the staff report). That implies 80 to 85 basis points of GDP in structural fiscal consolidation. But, in the staff working paper (not formal advice, but it clearly reflects the IMF’s overall recommendations), the preferred policy scenario shows an 80 basis point of GDP increase in temporary transfers and public wages to support the proposed incomes policy (this is in the working paper appendix, in table I.1 on p. 33). Net it all out; the result is basically a neutral stance, not the consolidation I initially suspected. The 0.5 percent of GDP fall in general government net lending/borrowing in table 2 on p. 25 of the working paper stems from a fall in interest payments and an increase in nominal GDP that is projected from the new incomes policy.* Actually if you look at table 4 in the staff report, Japan’s is expected to receive more in interest income than in pays out in interest in 2017. Japan’s government is projected receive 1.6 percent of GDP in interest on its assets (including its foreign reserves, which are largely held by the ministry of finance) and pay 1.3 percent of GDP in interest on its debt. The total fiscal deficit is thus smaller than the primary fiscal deficit in 2017. Welcome to the world of negative interest rates. The same methodology can be applied to deduce the IMF’s proposed fiscal stance for 2018. It generates a small proposed fiscal expansion in 2018, as the contraction from the roll-off of past stimulus is smaller (table 3 of the staff report shows a smaller change in the primary balance in 2018 than in 2017) and there is an ongoing increase in temporary transfers. Alas, these calculations are not totally straight-forward: getting the right answer requires two documents, and an appendix table! Using the change in the structural balance rather than the change in the structural primary balance also generates a slightly different result (a modest consolidation in 2017). A box that pulled together and quantified the Fund’s proposed offsets to the consolidation measures proposed for 2017 would have been helpful. I trust numbers in tables more than words. There have been too many stimulus packages in Japan that haven’t actually stimulated the economy, as one package just offset the roll-off of an earlier package.* A flat 2017, slightly expansionary 2018, and then a period of steady consolidation doesn’t actually detract from the core of my initial argument. I was focused on the impact of the IMF’s policy recommendations on global current account adjustment. The Fund is still recommending a medium-term fiscal consolidation in Japan, one that on its own would be expected to raise Japan’s current account surplus over time. And the proposed medium-term fiscal consolidations in the eurozone, Japan, and China still dwarf the (very modest) medium-term fiscal expansions proposed for Sweden and Korea. As a result external rebalancing—a reduction in the size of both external surpluses and external deficits—necessarily would have to be achieved through a larger fiscal consolidation in countries around the world that now run external deficits than in the countries that now have external surpluses. For a fiscal expansion in the surplus countries to contribute meaningfully to external rebalancing, the Fund will either need to recommend sustained fiscal deficits in countries like Japan, or encourage countries with both trade and fiscal surpluses (Korea and Germany) to move into fiscal deficit, not stop at fiscal balance. Such is the math. Paul Krugman though was more irked by the near-term impact of the IMF’s recommendations on demand. I suspect Dr. Krugman would prefer that the Fund embrace a bolder fiscal relaunch, especially with Japan stuck at the zero ten year bound (see Cecchetti and Schoenholtz, among others). A government that makes more on its lending than in pays on its borrowing probably has a bit of fiscal space.** But directionally, in Japan, the IMF is pushing (softly) in the right direction (at least in 2018). And, well, if the IMF can propose a few basis points of fiscal expansion in Japan over the next couple of years, I would hope it could do the same for the eurozone. *** * The paragraph in the staff report that I thought outlined the IMF’s recommended pace of consolidation (paragraph 28) only applies if Japan doesn’t adopt the IMF’s proposed incomes policy. I confess I missed the text in italics that limited the advice in paragraphs 27 and 28 to the "no reforms, no incomes policy" case; mea culpa. ** On net, Japan’s government is forecast by the IMF to receive more interest income than it pays (remember Japan has substantial financial assets, net debt is much smaller than gross debt) from 2017 to 2020 (see Table 3 on p. 40 of the staff report). Perhaps that will change with the BoJ’s new policy, as the Bank of Japan now doesn’t want the ten year JGB rate to be substantially negative—but probably it will not change by much. *** And do so without relying on the creation of new fiscal capacity at the euro-level. Common fiscal institutions are a good idea for the medium-term but the reality right now is that the eurozone’s aggregate fiscal policy is the sum of the national fiscal policies of its member states.
  • G20 (Group of Twenty)
    Global Economics Monthly: September 2016
    Bottom Line: At the Group of Twenty (G20) Summit in Hangzhou, China, leaders called for governments to do more to support growth, but offered little in the way of new measures. Quietly, and away from the G20 spotlight, fiscal policy is becoming more expansionary, but current policies are unlikely to provide a meaningful boost to growth or soothe rising populist pressures. Fiscal Stances in G20 Countries Last week’s Hangzhou communique disappointed observers hoping for a growth-boosting package of fiscal and structural reforms. Aside from cementing previous agreements on climate and tax compliance, there were no real economic achievements. A coordinated fiscal stimulus package from G20 countries, like in 2009, will not occur this year. Nonetheless, a careful look at the data shows a shift across the G20 countries toward larger fiscal deficits and, in a few cases, toward a more expansionary spending policy. Japan, China, the periphery of Europe, and some emerging markets all display this shift. Even in the United States, the fiscal squeeze of recent years has begun to ease. However, additional fiscal stimulus seems unlikely. Many countries remain hamstrung by high debt levels and gridlocked politics, and other countries, such as Germany, continue to resist using available fiscal space to boost European activity above its trend rate. As a result, global growth is likely to remain anemic. The G20 Call to Action  Beginning in February, G20 finance ministers and central bank governors have called repeatedly for more aggressive growth-oriented policies in their communique: "Over the last several years, the G20 has made important achievements to strengthen growth, investment and financial stability. We are taking actions to foster confidence and preserve and strengthen the recovery. We will use all policy tools—monetary, fiscal and structural—individually and collectively to achieve these goals. Monetary policies will continue to support economic activity and ensure price stability, consistent with central banks’ mandates, but monetary policy alone cannot lead to balanced growth. Our fiscal strategies aim to support the economy and we will use fiscal policy flexibly to strengthen growth, job creation and confidence, while enhancing resilience and ensuring debt as a share of GDP is on a sustainable path." This message has been reinforced by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and other international organizations with increasing urgency and anxiety as the year has gone on, most recently in the IMF’s report for the G20 summit. Observers have scrutinized each G20 statement for evidence of policies that would match the G20’s words. Time and again, those wishing for growth-oriented policies have been disappointed. Still, looking across the G20, in most cases fiscal policy has been easing in practice (both compared to last year and to forecasts for 2016 made at the start of the year), in some cases substantially. This easing occurred through allowing larger deficits (Canada and the United States), reducing surpluses (Germany), or delaying planned deficit reduction (France, Italy, and Japan). The exceptions include Latin America and Russia, where domestic pressures are forcing consolidation. Although the weakening in fiscal policy has been the autonomous result of a weaker global outlook (what economists call automatic stabilizers) in some cases, part of the loosening is the result of specific policies that will have a sustained impact. Notably, stimulus packages were announced this year in several countries. In March, Canada promised 3 percent of gross domestic product (GDP). In June, South Korea promised 1.2 percent of GDP. (My colleague Brad Setser has pointed out the limitations of the Korean effort.) In August, Japan announced a package of 6.7 percent of GDP, including loans. Japan’s package is coupled with the long-expected decision to defer the planned hike in the consumption tax, both of which are expected to boost growth by 0.6 percent in 2017. This cumulatively represents a swing of more than 1 percent in Japan’s fiscal position. Most important, China has introduced a substantial fiscal stimulus over the course of the year, which has provided tangible support to demand, though not enough to meaningfully reduce the external imbalances the country faces. These efforts include a loan-bond swap program for local governments to reduce debt costs, new infrastructure investment, and tax cuts. Although the Chinese government released new details of its plan after the summit, the plan does not appear to move fiscal policy beyond what was previously expected. The IMF argues that China’s fiscal deficit, measured comprehensively, stands in excess of 10 percent, and urges caution going forward to contain financial risks, including the weak health of local governments. Others disagree with the IMF’s assessment. As a result, the overall fiscal thrust (that is, the net boost to demand adjusting for changes in the economic cycle) of the eurozone, Japan, United Kingdom, and United States (the so-called G4) has turned positive in 2016 for the first time since 2010.  Figure 1. G4 Fiscal Stance Source: JP Morgan Fiscal Expansion, Not Policy Coordination Fiscal expansion’s many supporters believe that monetary policy has become less effective in recent years with interest rates already at low or negative levels. Further, research by the IMF and others on the experience in Europe after the crisis in 2010 has argued that the impact of fiscal spending (“fiscal multipliers”) is greater when interest rates are zero. In this regard, potentially high payoffs to greater infrastructure and public goods spending would appear to make a great deal of sense with rates low, a point reinforced by the IMF’s recent call for a substantial new infrastructure spending effort. Some economists have explicitly linked these arguments to efforts to address the anxiety now seen across the industrial world, calling for a “responsible nationalism.” However, it is worth emphasizing that a reorientation of spending, with the same overall deficit or surplus, could also address the need for more inclusive growth and assuage concerns of those who feel left behind by globalization. Others have gone further and called for fiscal expansion directly financed by central bank money creation (“helicopter money”). Although these arguments have broad or, in the case of helicopter money, growing appeal among economists, they have not seemed to affect the politics in major countries. On the surface, the fiscal policies of the major countries have hardened in recent years, making compromise more difficult. From this perspective, recent fiscal moves do not appear to be a coordinated act or a stealth policy initiative representing a successful G20 process. In each of the cases above, domestic politics have driven policy decisions, and global debates have played a limited role. Regarding the weak global growth environment as a common factor, I have argued elsewhere that the growth environment should be differentiated from true policy coordination. A more important question, from a growth perspective, is whether it is enough. Again, it is hard to argue that the scope for fiscal policy is exhausted, and indeed the IMF and others maintain that the major surplus countries have the fiscal space to provide additional demand support. The problem: the most significant unused space in the G20 is in Germany, and aside from a proposed 3.7 percent increase in spending (some of which is associated with the migration crisis) and some tax cuts, there appears to be little political room for a change in fiscal policy ahead of fall 2017 elections. These dynamics were on display in last week’s G20 meeting. Germany was quick to put down talk of coordinated action, and China, though supportive of additional growth, was clear that it had done all it can. The United States made the case, as it has in the past, for the fuller use of available fiscal space, but its ability to contribute is stymied by domestic politics. Earlier today, U.S. Treasury Secretary Jack Lew claimed the debate between austerity and growth is over and signaled new fiscal measures would be coming, but it is reasonable to be skeptical about this claim. Encouraging other people to spend their money seems to be the only thing that G20 leaders are able to agree on. What Happens Next Year In the United States, Donald Trump and Hillary Clinton have both put forward expansionary spending proposals, though Trump’s is far more so. But if the United States retains a divided government (as markets appear to expect), it is unlikely that either candidate would see his or her policies approved as president. Still, it is reasonable to expect at least some easing of spending caps, which would allow U.S. policy to become expansionary. In sum, fiscal policy has been responsive to events over the past year, and has provided support for growth in the face of substantial political and economic headwinds, including Brexit. But this easing was more the result of countries acting in their own interest than the result of coordinated action or a breakthrough at the G20. Further, there does not appear to be much more fiscal easing in the pipeline, nor even a reorientation that would address the populist concerns of the electorate. Those who want more aggressive fiscal support for inclusive growth will be disappointed by last week’s meeting. Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon Ukraine One year after Ukraine’s debt restructuring deal, investor confidence, rattled by continuing conflicts in the country’s east, remains cautious and fragile. What is equally worrying is Ukraine’s slow progress in implementing needed reforms, which has caused a delay in completing the second review of its IMF program and receiving the next tranche of aid. An IMF board meeting is scheduled for September 14.  Emerging Market Debt Corporate debt in emerging markets will likely experience a negative net issuance of $21 billion in 2016, with $118 billion maturing after nearly a decade of rapid expansion. Although this deleveraging process soothes the anxiety about high debt, the repayment ability of some corporations is still in question. The process also reflects debt-issuing companies’ rising concerns about investment profitability and the broader sluggish macroeconomic environment. Venezuela The crisis continues to deepen in Venezuela, underscored by a sharp recent deterioration in oil production, but the government is moving forward with a bond swap to make fall payments on state and energy-company debt. Still, default is a question of when, not if. 
  • China
    IMF Cannot Quit Fiscal Consolidation (in Asian Surplus Countries)
    In theory, the IMF now wants current account surplus countries to rely more heavily on fiscal stimulus and less on monetary stimulus. This shift makes sense in a world marked by low interest rates, the risk that surplus countries will export liquidity traps to deficit economies, and concerns about contagious secular stagnation. Fiscal expansion tends to lower the surplus of surplus countries and regions, while monetary expansion tends to increase external surpluses. And large external surpluses should be a concern in a world where imbalances in goods trade are once again quite large—though the goods surpluses now being chalked up in many Asian countries are partially offset by hard-to-track deficits in “intangibles” (to use an old term), notably China’s ongoing deficit in investment income and its ever-rising and ever-harder-to-track deficit in tourism. In practice, though, the Fund seems to be having trouble actually advocating fiscal expansion in any major economy with a current account surplus. Best I can tell, the Fund is encouraging fiscal consolidation in China, Japan, and the eurozone. These economies have a combined GDP of close to $30 trillion. The Fund, by contrast, is, perhaps, willing to encourage a tiny bit of fiscal expansion in Sweden (though that isn’t obvious from the 2015 staff report) and in Korea—countries with a combined GDP of $2 trillion.* I previously have noted that the Fund is advocating a 2017 fiscal consolidation for the eurozone, as the consolidation the Fund advocates in France, Italy, and Spain would overwhelm the modest fiscal expansion the Fund proposed in the Netherlands (The IMF is recommending that Germany stay on the fiscal sidelines in 2017). The same seems to be true in East Asia’s main surplus economies. Take the Fund’s advice on China. The Fund thinks that the right measure of China’s fiscal position is what the Fund calls the "augmented fiscal balance." And the Fund thinks that the augmented deficit is too big, and China should do modest consolidation in 2017.** "The projected increase in the augmented deficit in 2016 is thus not warranted from a structural perspective. Neither is it warranted from a cyclical perspective given the growth outlook. For 2017, a moderate reduction of the augmented deficit seems appropriate. Only if growth threatens to fall sharply (well below staff’s projection of 6.2 percent) should the deficit widen.” (emphasis added; paragraph 36, on p. 23 of the staff report) To be fair, the Fund isn’t calling for on-balance sheet fiscal consolidation, and even seems open to breaching the 3 percent of GDP limit for the headline deficit if that is needed to support more aggressive reforms. Directionally, though, the Fund still wants consolidation. Take the Fund’s advice on Japan. The first consumption take hike—from 5 to 8 percent—didn’t go that well. Consumption never recovered, and the economy lost momentum. But rather than reconsider consumption tax based consolidation, the Fund wants Japan to double down and commit to raise the consumption tax to 15 percent (rather than 10 percent): “a gradual increase in the consumption tax towards at least 15 percent, e.g., in increments of 0.5–1 percentage points over regular intervals, would better balance the objectives of supporting growth and achieving fiscal sustainability in the long run. … Starting the increases as soon as possible and replacing the currently planned 2019 hike with such a pre-announced, gradual path would enhance the credibility of the long-run fiscal adjustment effort..." (paragraph 23, on p. 14 of the staff report) That isn’t exactly a call to use the fiscal arrow to relaunch Japanese demand growth. The Fund is calling for slower and more predictable pace of consolidation, but it is still calling for consolidation, and a form of consolidation that would weigh most heavily on households. Monetary and fiscal policies would work in opposite directions. Japan is a hard case. It has an unusually high level of public debt. It also has an unusually low interest rate on that debt. And fiscal risks are reduced so long as the stock of debt actually held by the public is falling fast: Think of a 5 percent of GDP fiscal deficit and annual purchases by the Bank of Japan (BoJ) of 15 percent of GDP (Or take a look at Figure 3 in Toby Nangle’s paper). With fiscal consolidation at a steady 0.5 percent of GDP pace needed for the next ten to fifteen-plus years according to the Fund (see paragraph 23 of the staff report) it is a little hard to see how the BoJ can stop buying any time soon—so if Japan adopted the Fund’s advice, the fall in debt held in the market would likely be quite fast.*** And what of Korea? The details of the Fund’s advice for Korea are still not out. But there is no real evidence the Fund wants a significant, sustained fiscal loosening in Korea, even though Korea has low government debt, no fiscal deficit to speak of and a $100 billion-plus current account surplus (7-8 percent of Korea’s GDP). The Fund’s forecast, if I read it correctly, projects that Korea’s general government will return to a fiscal surplus of 1.0 percent of GDP over time.**** Korea needs to ease just to avoid tightening, so to speak. Asia’s two big surplus countries (China and Japan) no doubt present a slightly more complicated case than the eurozone taken as a whole. The eurozone is in primary balance, and in aggregate, has only a modest deficit. The absolute size of China’s augmented deficit and Japan’s primary deficit no doubt bother many at the Fund. On the other hand both China and Japan run significant external surpluses even with sizable fiscal deficits; the obvious implication is that without those fiscal deficits the size of their external surpluses would be much bigger. Korea has no fiscal deficit to speak of, and a current account surpluses that is bigger, relative to its GDP, than the current account of either China or Japan. Bottom line: if the Fund wants fiscal expansion in surplus countries to drive external rebalancing and reduce current account surpluses, it actually has to be willing to encourage major countries with large external surpluses to do fiscal expansion. Finding limited fiscal space in Sweden and perhaps Korea won’t do the trick. 20 or 30 basis points of fiscal expansion in small economies won’t move the global needle. Not if China, Japan, and the eurozone all lack fiscal space and all need to consolidate over time. [*] See table 3 of this report for the Fund’s assessment of the gap between a country’s 2015 fiscal balance and its appropriate long-term balance. Sweden should go from a surplus of 0.3 percent of GDP to balance, and Korea from a surplus of 0.6 percent of GDP to rough balance (a deficit of 0.1 percent of GDP) [**] The IMF is not calling, thankfully, for China to reduce its on-budget fiscal deficit, which is forecast to remain at close to 3 percent of GDP for some time. But the Fund is clearly calling for a significant overall consolidation, along with slower growth in private credit. [***] I assume the Fund expects that Japan’s supplementary budget will offset the 0.8 percent of GDP fiscal consolidation that the Fund projects for calendar 2017 in Japan. The staff report didn’t seem to warn of the demand side impact of allowing past stimulus packages to roll-off without being replaced with new stimulus. The tendency toward consolidation from the roll-off of past stimulus packages makes it hard to assess the actual fiscal impetus in Japan, as Japan is on a bit of a treadmill where ongoing temporary stimulus has to be replaced by new stimulus just to avoid a negative fiscal impulse. [****] Korea’s national pension system collects significantly more than it takes in, generating a substantial surplus. The headline fiscal deficit of the government thus differs from the general government’s fiscal balance. Note: I initially wrote that the IMF forecasts Korea’s general government balance to rise to a surplus of 1.5%. It looks to be 1% (using general government net borrowing/ lending). I also corrected a couple of spelling errors.
  • Europe
    Why Is The IMF Pushing Fiscal Consolidation in the Eurozone in 2017?
    The eurozone collectively has a substantial external surplus, and its economy is operating below potential. In the framework set out in the IMF’s external balance assessment, that pretty clearly calls for fiscal expansion: "Surplus countries that have domestic slack need to rely more on fiscal policy easing, which would address both their output gaps and their external gaps... Meanwhile, deficit countries should actively use monetary policy, where available, to close both internal and external gaps." But is the IMF following its own advice (for a currency union that has an external surplus and domestic slack, I am well aware of the fact that the eurozone is not a single country with a single fiscal policy) and actually recommending a fiscal expansion in the eurozone? Best I can tell, no. Not for 2017. The IMF of course is for more fiscal stimulus at the European level. But that is a hope, not a reality. The capacity for a common eurozone fiscal policy conducted through borrowing by the center doesn’t currently exist, and it realistically isn’t going to materialize next year. That means the eurozone’s aggregate fiscal impulse is the sum of the fiscal impulses of each of its main economies. What does the IMF recommend there? In Italy the IMF seems to want about a half a point of structural fiscal consolidation (see paragraph 35 of the staff report). In France, the same (see paragraph 33 of the staff report). In Spain, the last IMF article IV called for a half a point of consolidation as well (see paragraph 33). That though is likely to be ratcheted up, as Spain hasn’t done much consolidation over the past two years and now will need to engage in a major consolidation to get to the Commission’s 3 percent of GDP fiscal target in 2018. Spain, Italy, and France collectively account for a bit more of the eurozone’s GDP than Germany and the Netherlands. So, is the IMF recommending enough fiscal expansion in Germany and the Netherlands to assure a positive fiscal impulse for the eurozone as a whole? No. The IMF is now advocating that Germany avoid returning to a structural surplus, and invest any windfall savings from higher than expected revenues or lower interest rates. But the IMF isn’t advocating Germany do any more on net than it already had done. Germany delivered a significant stimulus is 2016, but it was a one and done stimulus. Germany isn’t projected to generate a positive fiscal impulse in 2017.* The Netherlands needs stimulus on purely domestic grounds given persistent weakness in household demand and an ongoing output gap (see the "Tricky Balance" chart in the IMF’s external balance assessment). And the IMF did recommend a modest fiscal expansion in its last assessment of the Dutch economy. But also it didn’t protest too much when the Dutch government politely declined. See paragraphs 14 and 15 of the 2015 staff report. Bottom line: Germany’s 2017 fiscal impulse is projected to be neutral. The fiscal expansion the IMF recommended in the Netherlands for 2017 is not likely to be adopted and even if adopted it would be too small to offset the fiscal consolidation the IMF is recommending in Spain, Italy, and France. Given the weight of France, Italy and Spain in the eurozone, this implies the IMF is recommending that the eurozone as a whole consolidate next year. And in the IMF’s global framework, that implies the IMF is currently recommending policies that would tend to raise the eurozone’s external surplus. That goes to a larger global problem. The IMF’s framework for looking at external balances says, more or less, that intervention in the foreign exchange market has only a modest impact on external balances.** The policies that matter are healthcare spending, and of course, fiscal policy. The IMF always lives up to its mostly fiscal reputation. The implication, if the IMF wants to be symmetric and worry about global demand as well as global balance of payments adjustment, is that the IMF needs to be as aggressive in recommending fiscal expansion in surplus countries as it is in recommending fiscal consolidation in deficit countries. Judging by its recommendations in Europe, it still has a way to go. In addition to watching the IMF’s aggregate recommendation for the eurozone, I also will be watching the IMF’s 2017 fiscal recommendation for Korea—which has a German-sized current account surplus and, broadly speaking, a German fiscal policy (counting the off-budget surplus in Korea’s social security fund, Korea ran a general government surplus in 2015).*** And its last stimulus package seems to lack what the Japanese would call fresh water. There is of course a second, more straight forward argument for why the IMF might want to encourage Germany to do a bit more public investment in 2017: It offers the most obvious way to help insulate Germany from a slowdown in British demand. The IMF’s initial analysis of Brexit suggested it might knock 20 basis points off eurozone growth in 2017. The hit to Germany, though, was bigger—more like 40 basis points. Logical, given Germany’s greater dependence on exports. Germany’s 2017 nominal wage growth—judging from the contracts agreed this spring—also looks to be slower than in 2016. All in all, it would seem like there is ample reason for the IMF to encourage Germany to offset the impact of the drag expected from Brexit with a looser fiscal policy in 2017 and 2018, even if that means Germany would need to run small structural fiscal deficits for a time. It would support German growth in the face of an expected external shock. It would help ease the pressure on monetary policy when the ECB is at the zero bound. It would make it easier for Italy, Spain, and France to offset the demand drag from fiscal consolidation through exports, and thus facilitate the eurozone’s internal rebalancing. And it would help reduce the eurozone’s contribution to global current account imbalances. Note: edited slightly after publication; I had "internal" when I meant "external" in the last paragraph * Germany did provide a solid (around 1 percent of GDP) fiscal stimulus in 2016 in response to the migrant crisis, as the IMF estimates it moved from a 70 basis points of GDP general government surplus to a 30 basis point of GDP general government deficit. But now that Germany no longer has a surplus, the politics of further stimulus get complicated. The IMF’s staff report emphasized that any further public investment needs to be Within the fiscal rules ("Fiscal resources available within the envelope defined by the fiscal rules, including in case of overperformance, should be used to finance additional public investments...") and the debt brake doesn’t leave much space (see paragraph 49 of the 2016 staff report; the fiscal impulse is from table 2 of the staff report. ** This gets technical. In the IMF’s analytical framework, the intervention variable is interacted with the capital controls variable, reducing its impact. The capital controls variable is never “1.” For China, for example, it was 0.5 last year. So a percentage point of GDP in Chinese intervention could not have more than a roughly 17 basis point impact on the current account (the 0.45 intervention coefficient is multiplied by capital controls, which are now rated at 0.38 on a 0 to 1 scale. For Korea, a percentage point of GDP intervention could not have an impact of more than 6 basis points, given the 0.13 intensity of Korea’s controls. This is well below the impact that the Peterson Institute’s Joe Gagnon has estimated. And the impact is further reduced by the fact that the relevant variable is the gap between a country’s current level of controls and the optimal level of controls. So if the IMF (wisely) believes China isn’t ready yet to liberalize its financial account, the impact of intervention in generating a “policy gap” falls further. Right now, given the size of the capital controls gap for China, a dollar of intervention in China results in only a ten cent change in the current account. It doesn’t matter much now, as emerging markets sold reserves in 2015 and so far in 2016. But the net effect is that in the IMF’s framework, intervention never had much of an aggregate impact even back when there was a lot of intervention. *** The IMF is recommending medium-term fiscal consolidation in Japan, China, and the eurozone. Fairly substantial consolidations too (see table 3 of this report, look at what the IMF calls P* or "optimal" policies and compare that with the current estimated fiscal balance; the full underlying analytics are here). It is recommending a small medium-term fiscal expansion in Sweden and Korea. Both countries ran general government surpluses in 2015, and the IMF is calling them to bring those surpluses to zero or run a small (10 basis points of GDP) general government fiscal deficit. But the resulting swing in the fiscal balance is modest relative to the size of the Swedish and Korean current account surplus. For Germany, the IMF is recommending a fiscal expansion relative to its 2015 surplus; but, as noted above, that stimulus occurred in 2016, and the IMF isn’t currently calling for more stimulus. I should note here that the recommended fiscal stance in the IMF’s external balance assessment is for the medium term; just because the Fund recommends a medium term on-budget consolidation for say China doesn’t mean it recommends an immediate on-budget fiscal consolidation. That said, given China’s extremely high national savings rate and the need for corporate deleveraging, I personally do not see why China could not sustain on-budget fiscal deficits of around 2 percent of GDP in the medium term.
  • Global
    The World Next Week: April 7, 2016
    Podcast
    The IMF spring meeting takes place, the fallout continues over the release of the Panama papers, and marathons are held at the North Pole and in North Korea.
  • Economics
    Global Economics Monthly: March 2016
    Bottom Line: The International Monetary Fund (IMF) deserves credit for effectively responding to the global and European financial crises. However, the institution will face different and potentially more difficult challenges in the next five years as it struggles to come to terms with a changing international power order and lending rules that are not well suited to address future crises.1 Five Years Defined by the Euro Crisis Christine Lagarde assumed the helm of the IMF in July 2011 at a moment of turbulence for the Fund. Roiled by the resignation of Dominique Strauss-Kahn two months earlier, the IMF was under attack on a number of fronts. The Greek adjustment effort, designed by and strongly supported by the Fund, was on the brink of failure; the IMF decision to provide one-third of the financing for Europe’s rescue packages had come under harsh criticism from emerging market members as a special deal for Europe; and there was a growing perception that the Fund was out of touch with the views of rising powers such as China, India, and Brazil. Efforts to strengthen its policy advice outside of financial programs—“surveillance” in Fund-speak—had run out of steam as the global financial crisis began to recede and major industrial countries found policy coordination inconvenient. Significant questions were being raised regarding whether the Fund would be able to deal with threats then facing the global economy. Difficult times demonstrate the importance of the IMF, and now, five years later, a brighter take on the Fund’s role is possible. A global recovery has taken hold and, although credit rests more with national authorities and central bankers, the IMF’s steady support for the European periphery no doubt helped stem the panic, shore up confidence, and provide essential resources to needed financing packages. The Fund has acknowledged that some of the early programs were poorly designed (for example, in underestimating the drag from fiscal consolidation), but it is unclear what could have been done differently absent additional (and more timely) finance from European creditors to allow a slower pace of adjustment. I am more sympathetic to the charge that Fund decisions to delay restructurings in Greece in 2010–2011 and Ukraine in 2014 led to deals that were “too little, too late,” resulting in new lending rules in January 2016. I have concerns with the new approach, as I note below, but on the whole it represents a sensible effort to reduce crisis risks. Looking Ahead The IMF was not the only institution that failed to anticipate the global risks now roiling markets: a crisis in China and its contagion to emerging markets already shaken by lower commodity prices, capital outflows, and weak global demand. But it will be graded on how it responds. Latin America should be a particular concern for the IMF. Three of the largest countries in the region—Argentina, Brazil, and Venezuela—face significant economic challenges in the year ahead, and a crisis in any of these three countries could have profound spillover effects. None of these countries is close to asking the IMF for its financial support. But if that were to happen, the odds that the IMF will be asked to intervene with sizeable resources on multiple fronts is higher now than in many years. Beyond the challenges in the year ahead, two interlinked problems stand out in particular. China and the Rising Power Question One of the central challenges for the Fund going forward is its shifting relationship with China and the other emerging powers. Following the move by the Group of Twenty (G20) to meet at the leaders’ level in 2008, and the successful effort to bolster Fund resources to deal with the crisis, the IMF faced a double-edged challenge. It had to create a role for these countries and incentivize their fuller participation in the leadership of the international financial institutions, while at the same time strengthening its policy dialogue with these economies. On both counts, the Fund has struggled. On the representation side, it was hamstrung by the failure, until recently, of the U.S. government to approve a package of reform measures agreed to in 2010, though it did address one Chinese ambition with its support for inclusion of the renminbi (RMB) in the Fund’s currency basket, the special drawing rights (SDR). Still, the creation of the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB), the New Development Bank (formerly BRICs Bank), and talk of enhanced regional swap lines raises questions about the coherence and consistency of the global crisis architecture that places the Fund at the center.  In a recent speech, Lagarde highlighted two roles for the Fund going forward: providing a better framework for capital flows and strengthening the global financial safety net. For the Fund, that means a role at the center of a strengthened set of swap lines between central banks in advanced and emerging economies. That may be a bridge too far for leading central banks and governments. But absent concerted action, the temptation exists to continue the regionalization of rescue efforts, including in Asia through an expansion of the Chiang Mai Initiative, a currency-swap network in the region.  The Fund’s failure to come to terms with China’s macroeconomic imbalances that persisted through the past few years was a larger concern. Certainly, a careful reading of the Fund’s annual reports on the Chinese economy can find warnings concerning the imbalances that have roiled markets since last summer. However, it does seem that deference to the Chinese authorities muted those warnings and the Fund’s voice was not an effective signal to markets or the public more generally. To the IMF’s credit, the reports urged a cautious response to financial deregulation, stressing the importance of careful sequencing and hard budget constraints on firms before markets were opened. That said, the public perception now seems to be that the Fund was a cheerleader for the market reforms that led to the current crisis, which cannot help but damage the IMF’s credibility on this issue. Related to its relationship with the rising powers, the Fund needs to decide how it interacts with European economies, clarifying the proper relationship with Europe's currency union and regional relationships. “Grexit” could reemerge as a challenge for markets, if agreement is not reached on economic reforms and debt relief in coming months. Even if agreement is reached, the IMF will be expected to lend to Greece in a highly risky environment. More broadly, the right lessons need to be drawn about the best role for the IMF to play when countries, without an independent monetary policy and with significant pan-European constraints on fiscal policy, have a crisis meriting IMF support. The Fund’s Role as Fire Department There is a broader issue at play here. Looking back to at least the Mexico and Asian crisis packages of the 1990s, we have seen a Fund that is struggling to come to terms with increasingly large demands on its resources. This period has also witnessed rapid growth in financial markets and the expansion and greater integration of major emerging markets into the global financial system. This means that the financial requirements of a rescue package for one of these countries have grown much faster than the Fund’s resources. In other words, the world is getting bigger more quickly than the Fund’s resources have grown (see figure 1). The IMF was never intended to be a lender of last resort, though at times it benefited from markets believing that it was. At the same time, despite its de facto senior status, it has grown increasingly concerned about the demands on its balance sheet from increasingly large financing programs. It is becoming clearer that Fund money alone is not going to be enough and that the timing and scale of debt restructurings will be a function of the adequacy of financing rather than whether debt is above an arbitrary threshold. FIGURE 1. IMF RESOURCES VERSUS NEEDS  Sources: IMF; World Bank International Debt Statistics. Last month, the IMF agreed to new rules guiding lending for large-scale, difficult programs. It now has embraced a greater reliance on “reprofiling”—restructurings aimed at keeping creditors in the game through an extension of maturities with little loss in market value—and wants its lending in risky, high-profile cases to be limited to situations where there is significant burden sharing with other official creditors. This solution, designed with Greece (and Europe more generally) in mind, does little to address a possible crisis in Latin America (or other places where there isn’t a group of official creditors willing to provide junior financing). Hopefully, this will trigger a broader debate about how to allocate the burden of financing these packages. The answer to that question will determine whether the Fund is an effective leader of the global effort to prevent and resolve crises. Stay tuned. Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon Venezuela Time could be running short for a Venezuelan government facing a deep recession, severe shortages, and hyperinflation—a debt default could come this year. China The risk of a maxi-devaluation continues to weigh on Chinese markets. Central banks Negative interest rates have become more common in the industrial world, raising questions over whether central banks have the capacity to lift growth. 1 This newsletter draws on a longer analysis of the Fund’s record and future challenges. 
  • China
    Global Economics Monthly: November 2015
    Bottom Line: Emerging markets face the greatest risk of contagion from a hard landing in China. The threat seems modest compared to the Asian financial crisis or Great Recession, but, in the event of a crisis, policymakers may not be up to the task of an aggressive and coordinated response. At the recent International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank annual meetings in Peru, the central debate was over whether China’s economic crisis represents a systemic threat to the global economy. August’s sharp drop in financial markets—now partly reversed—was to some an overreaction to China’s economic problems and to others a harbinger of worse to come. Trade flows have dropped, with the commodity-exporting countries hit particularly hard, but it was the emerging markets’ financial linkages to China that drew the most discussion. The IMF’s Global Financial Stability Report made the controversial argument that high levels of debt and leverage in major emerging markets create a systemic risk that could endanger the global recovery. That was the story from Lima. The consensus of mainstream economists is that these China-driven concerns, although mounting and worrisome, do not match the threat posed by the 1997 Asian financial crisis or the Great Recession. In the years since the Asian financial crisis, many emerging-market governments have built large levels of international reserves to provide a buffer against such shocks. China illustrates the trend: despite massive losses over the past three months, its international reserves are more than $3 trillion, well in excess of obligations coming due (even acknowledging that not all of the government’s reserves are liquid and useable). In addition, structural reforms have opened economies and made them more flexible, and financial regulation is more focused on limiting risk from large exchange-rate movements. Lessons have been learned. Perhaps most importantly, there is a far greater degree of exchange-rate flexibility in the major emerging markets now than there was in the 1990s, which has prevented substantial currency misalignments of the magnitude that triggered exchange-rate crises in the past. Goldman Sachs, for example, argues that emerging markets are far more competitive now than at the start of earlier crises (see figure 1, where low values reflect greater undervaluation).  FIGURE 1. EMERGING MARKET CURRENCY VALUATION Source: Goldman Sachs, Investment Strategy Group, Investment Management Division © 2015 Reasons for Concern  Still, if there is a hard landing in China and a resulting reemergence of the kind of financial stress witnessed in August, policymakers must be prepared to respond. On this count, there are four reasons for concern. First, the scale of the financial imbalances is large. The massive growth in emerging markets, and their greater integration in global financial markets, has been reflected, in particular, by a rapid rise in corporate and household indebtedness and far more complex financial linkages than in the past. Corporate emerging-market debt now stands at $18 trillion, or close to 75 percent of gross domestic product (GDP), and leverage has soared. The Great Recession reminded us that interconnectedness—even more than the size of financial institutions—can be a recipe for crisis. The lack of transparency regarding China’s economic policies and relationships matters as well. China’s importance for financial markets and supply chains is not well understood, and a hard landing in China, renewed crisis in Europe, or even the anticipated normalization of U.S. monetary policy could cause real distress in countries as diverse as Brazil, Turkey, and Korea. Second, the currently weak global growth environment limits the scope for policymakers to respond, should demand fall sharply. A few years ago, the judgment that emerging markets had come out of the Great Recession with strong fiscal and monetary positions—“policy space”—provided optimism that these markets could outgrow the industrial world and would be able to adopt expansionary cyclical policies in the face of a global shock. That optimism is now dashed, in part reflecting that many countries’ strong fiscal positions have been wasted and market reforms rejected. Nowhere is that sense of lost opportunity more acute than in Brazil. Since taking office in 2011, the Dilma Rousseff administration has pursued an expansionary fiscal policy that appears not to have contributed much support to economic growth. Meanwhile, inflation is rising, and failure to address structural problems in the economy has lowered productivity and crippled private sector confidence. Unsuccessful efforts to restore fiscal balance this year have further undermined confidence in the government. As a result, Brazilian markets have come under increased market pressure. Third, the global fire station is poorly equipped to deal with future blazes. Over the past two decades, the policymaking community’s official resources to address crises have not kept pace with the rapid growth of financial markets. The IMF has seen its resources bolstered, but a recent reform package that would have strengthened its governance and ensured broad support for its crisis resolution efforts remains stuck in the U.S. Congress. At the same time, growing fiscal constraints in the major creditor countries limits the capacity of governments, most significantly in the United States and Europe, to contribute bilateral funds to rescue efforts. Coming up with the necessary official sector finance will pose an increasing challenge for dealing with protracted, large-scale financial crises. In Greece in 2012 and Ukraine this year, it was the inadequacy of official funding and the resultant financing gaps, as much as anything else, that dictated the timing and extent of private debt restructurings. Fourth, political pressures on governments are also limiting their ability to respond actively with financing and the other tools at their disposal—including regulatory measures and through the bully pulpit—to address market crises. In Europe, rising populism on both the left and the right, and bailout fatigue after years of crisis in the periphery, has weakened governments and reduced support for bailouts. In the United States, the Dodd-Frank Act and other postcrisis legislation and regulation limit the capacity of the Federal Reserve and Treasury to provide emergency support. In contrast, during the 1994 Mexican bailout and the 1997 Asian financial crisis, the creative use of U.S. economic power—including moral suasion on banks to participate in restructurings—played a central role in stabilizing markets. In recent years, the Group of Twenty (G20) has been the focus of policy coordination, but whether that group could find common cause as it did in 2008 remains a question. Crisis Preparedness Chinese policymakers have the tools and the resources to stabilize their economy in coming months, though the multiyear challenge of rebalancing and reforming their economy and dealing with the legacy of past overlending is still to be firmly addressed. Although a severe global financial crisis remains a tail risk and not the base case, governments should be prepared to respond. A strengthened and reenergized G20, an IMF with adequate resources and improved governance, and governments willing to act aggressively to deal with potential contagion are all needed to ensure that the downside scenario, if it occurs, does not become a major crisis.  Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon United States  While keeping the current interest rate unchanged, the Federal Reserve also signaled a possible rate increase in December and downplayed previously highlighted concerns over China.  Europe The European Central Bank (ECB) is likely to expand quantitative easing by December, though some ECB officials do not see a convincing reason for rush action.  China  The Chinese Communist Party, at its Fifth Plenum, has laid out the next Five Year Plan (2016–2020). Although its details are not yet public, the plan targets an annual growth of no less than 6.5 percent for the next five years. 
  • Economics
    Global Economics Monthly: August 2015
    Bottom Line: China’s request to include its currency, the renminbi (RMB), in an International Monetary Fund (IMF) currency basket is political as much as economic in intent and effect. The IMF is likely to decide late this year to include the RMB in the basket, known as the special drawing right (SDR), but the path to “yes” poses challenges to the IMF and the U.S. government and needs to be carefully managed. Every five years, the IMF updates the currency basket it uses to denominate its transactions. The SDR is used primarily in IMF operations, as well as in a small number of private and public transactions. Usually, these reviews are dry, technical affairs. This time is different, following the March 2015 request from the Chinese government to add the RMB to the basket. If agreed, the introduction of the RMB in the SDR represents a significant milestone in China’s transition to a less-regulated economy, and a further effort at global economic leadership following the launch of the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB) earlier this year. The Chinese request has drawn statements of support from a broad range of industrial and developing countries. The Obama administration’s position has been muted, signaling support for reforms that would make the RMB a truly international currency without stating whether there has been sufficient progress to justify U.S. support. The IMF analysis is unlikely to make a compelling case in either direction, presenting a range of indicators suggesting a mixed picture. The IMF staff recommended transitioning to the new basket in September 2016, nine months later than usual. This extended transition does not prejudge the decision on the RMB, but it would make it easier for markets to adjust to a new basket. A separate IMF board meeting later this year will be necessary to decide on the composition of the new SDR. Earlier this week, the IMF released a paper outlining the process of the review. SDR Algebra IMF loans are denominated in SDRs, but in practice countries can ask for, or pay, in any of the currencies in the basket when transacting with the IMF. Borrowers do bear the exchange risk of the basket denominated in SDRs, but they can hedge it, and there is increasing evidence that sovereign asset managers actively hedge such exposures. The SDR basket currently contains four currencies—the U.S. dollar, the euro, the Japanese yen, and the U.K. pound. Initially sixteen currencies, the SDR was reduced to five currencies in 1980 and to its current composition in 2000, after the introduction of the euro. The number of currencies in the basket has never been increased. The IMF has a two-tier test for inclusion in the SDR. The first test—a gateway for consideration as an SDR currency—aims to limit the basket to currencies that provide for stability in terms of the major currencies and that are “representative of those used in international transactions.” In practice, this means that the country needs to be a major trader, measured primarily by exports, without an excessively volatile currency. China was seen as meeting that test in 2010, and, as one of the world’s largest economies and exporters is certain to meet this test again in 2015. The second test, introduced in 1977 after the advent of the floating rate system, mandates that the currency be “freely useable,” meaning that it is “widely used to make payments for international transactions” and “is widely traded in the principal exchange markets,” as defined by IMF’s Articles of Agreement XXX(f) The interpretation of these criteria has evolved over time with innovation and the deepening of international capital markets, and is assessed by looking at a range of indicators. These include trade and trade credit, capital flows, forward markets, and the spread between buying and selling quotations for cross-border transactions denominated in that currency. The foreign exchange market for the currency needs to be deep and broad, so that, at a minimum, governments are able to buy and sell as needed for official transactions without causing large market moves. This focus on “widely used” and “widely traded” has proven the stumbling block for China. In 2010, the IMF staff argued that the RMB did not meet these criteria. The case for its inclusion is stronger now, but likely still to be mixed given the wide range of indicators that are examined and the inherent qualitative nature of the conditions. On economic grounds, this debate is a grey area without a definitive answer. Of particular concern to some is the lack of tradability in the United States; although the RMB has seventeen offshore clearing markets (including London and Germany), New York is not one of them. It is important to note that freely useable is not the same as freely convertible. Certainly, the RMB is not freely convertible and is unlikely to be so for some time. Freely useable is an easier test than full convertibility, and potentially a large number of countries meet this test. But because of the gateway criteria, only China can be considered for addition to the SDR this time. Still, critics of China have focused on the lack of convertibility as reason to deny the Chinese request. Markets Will Speculate There were once grand hopes that the SDR would grow into one of the major reserve currencies, but the private use of the SDR has been limited. With the rapid development of global foreign–exchange markets, investors can achieve the risk profile of the SDR reasonably easily and at low cost. Consequently, the SDR never achieved the scale or efficiencies to justify its widespread use. Currency speculation might occur during the nearly year-long period between the announcement of the decision to add the RMB and the changeover to the new basket, if market participants form views about how the Chinese will manage the exchange rate during that period. China could allow large exchange-rate movements once a decision has been made (locking in a depreciation, for example), or China might err toward stability. I lean toward the latter view. The introduction of a high-interest-rate currency into the basket will change the nature of the SDR. Because China’s interest rate is higher than that of the major industrial countries and is expected to remain so on average, the introduction of the RMB into the basket with a 10 to 15 percent weight will raise the interest rate on the SDR by thirty to forty basis points, small relative to normal monetary-policy cycles but still considerable. This would be the case for any fast-growing developing country in the process of convergence—currency depreciation would be expected to offset inflation differences, but real interest rates will be higher than in industrial countries. From that perspective, the risk-free nature of the SDR as an asset does change, borrowers from the IMF will pay more, and the value for investors shifts as well.  The Politics of the SDR One argument for Chinese participation in the SDR, as for other decisions regarding international institutions, is that these types of decisions anchor the reform process in China by offering visible symbols of the government’s commitment to reform. This argument has been made often by the Peoples Bank of China, for example, although this argument lost some credibility during the recent turmoil in Chinese markets. The subsequent herky-jerky market reaction by the government suggested an antireform bias (and provides an excuse for not liberalizing quickly). Nonetheless, the Chinese government does seem to recognize and acknowledge the need for a credible commitment to further reform in this area as part of the process on SDR inclusion. Opponents of adding the RMB to the SDR have expressed concern that it validates unfair trade and financial-services practices. For example, a June 2015 letter from Senators Chuck Schumer (D-NY) and Lindsey Graham (R-SC) to the IMF demanded that the RMB not be included in the SDR, arguing that the RMB remained significantly undervalued and that China’s economic reforms and efforts to liberalize currency and capital flows had yet to go far enough. From that perspective, the announcement of a decision late this year, when it is possible that Congress will be considering the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) and IMF quota reform, represents another communication challenge for the Obama administration, should the IMF decide to include the RMB in the SDR. Good things could come out of the negotiation around the Chinese request. China has until now failed to report foreign-exchange reserves to international databases—e.g., currency composition of official foreign-exchange reserves (COFER)—and could be a lot more transparent in its reserve operations. The Fund should seek commitments on this score and it is likely to do so. The broader question is over where China is going on market reform and whether this milestone will support liberalization. In the end, especially after the fiasco surrounding the U.S. objection to the establishment of the AIIB, it is important for the U.S. government to get this right. The U.S. position should support China making some significant steps ahead of the decision, including regarding transparency and continued moves to a more market-oriented exchange rate. The ultimate objective for the IMF will be a package of measures that can get the United States to “yes.” Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon Taper Tantrum 2.0? Ahead of a Federal Reserve decision to raise interest rates, expected between September and December, there is increased worry about the implications for emerging markets. Greece Negotiations Start Slowly Negotiators are aiming for a mid-August agreement, but another bridge loan likely will be needed. Brazil Worries Concerns that Brazil will lose its investment-grade rating underscore rising economic concerns.
  • Global
    The World Next Week: June 25, 2015
    Podcast
    Iran and the P5+1 reach a deadline for nuclear talks; Greece hits a payment deadline to the IMF and Brazilian President Dilma Rousseff meets with President Barack Obama.