• Turkey
    Why Democrats and Republicans Should Oppose Data Localization
    Anupam Chander is Martin Luther King, Jr. Research Professor and Director of the California International Law Center at UC Davis School of Law. He is the recipient of a Google Research Award supporting related research. Data localization, a term invented less than a handful of years ago, is getting a lot of attention—both for good and bad. The draft of the Democratic party platform includes a commitment to oppose data localization across the world, so that’s good. The fact that the party has to do so is distressing, indicating that data localization has become increasingly popular in some parts of the world. Opposing data localization should be a bipartisan endeavor, and Republicans this week should speak out against it because data localization harms freedom of speech, economic growth, and a free and open internet. Data localization is a government requirement that data should physically stay within a particular jurisdiction’s boundaries, perhaps subject to limited and onerous exceptions. For example, Russia passed a data localization law in 2014, requiring that data about Russians be held on a server within that country (though copies of the data can be moved abroad). While the Russian government justified it as necessary to mitigate U.S. spying and defend the country’s “digital sovereignty”, the law seems designed to help Russia’s own intelligence services by keeping information about Russians within their easy reach. Data localization not only helps local spies, but can be a good way to impede competition from abroad. Foreign companies face three unattractive options: (1) bear the costs of either building out new server facilities or renting space on local servers in each of the countries requiring data localization; (2) quit those markets; or (3) ignore the obligation and hope to escape scrutiny. These choices harm not only technology companies, but all companies, from General Electric to accounting firms to the local plumber. All companies hold data—about customers, employees, and visitors to their websites or mobile apps. Car companies increasingly receive data from their vehicles—witness Tesla’s remote monitoring of all of its car crashes. The town plumber too may store information about his or her customers often using a foreign cloud-based service. Data localization applies to all companies that gather data on individuals, meaning nearly all large and even small companies operating today. Localizing data in those foreign countries also means segregating data by country of origin, limiting the ability to do cross-country analytics. The largest companies are the ones most likely to be able to build out local data infrastructures; it is the small and medium sized companies who will either withdraw from markets or simply violate the law, unable to afford to comply. Local start-ups will find their choices of cloud and other service providers narrowed, and their expenses increased while their flexibilities are decreased. Many governments are keen on data localization because it helps them to assert greater control over their domestic citizenry. They can more easily track what their citizens do because their data is held on nearby computers. Governments can also bar foreign services on the ground that they don’t comply with data localization mandates. Data localization can be used to make it more difficult for their people to use foreign services like Facebook, Google, or Twitter to communicate with their countrymen and women. In May, Iran’s Supreme Council of Cyberspace declared, “Foreign messaging companies active in the country are required to transfer all data and activity linked to Iranian citizens into the country in order to ensure their continued activity.” In the wake of allegations of government corruption, the Turkish government in 2014 sought to ban Twitter entirely, though a Turkish constitutional court reversed the ban. If Turkey adopted a data localization mandate like Russia’s, it would be far easier to either bar Twitter for failing to comply, or to try to delete accounts (based on claims of defamation, etc.) because those accounts would be stored locally. Data localization proponents argue it is essential to protect data privacy. In reality, data localization reduces privacy for a number of reasons. First, data localization undermines the security of information by multiplying the number of data centers that companies have to monitor. Second, data localization limits our choice of service providers to those operating locally; protectionism, experience teaches, generally reduces the quality of a service. If one believes that one’s information is only safe in one’s home country, then that person should by all means choose a local provider. But data localization makes that choice for all people—telling folks they cannot use a provider using foreign computers even if they think it is more private and secure. Third, as seems to be the case in Russia and elsewhere, data localization increases the exposure of information to local authorities if the local surveillance law authorizes such snooping. Fundamentally, saying that only information is only safe if it stays within the country is akin to saying that you only trust goods produced in the United States or food produced here. In reality, even foreign goods or food can be safe, and local goods or food can also be unsafe. Data localization also undermines one of the internet’s greatest gifts: the ability of individuals to communicate with each other across borders and access information. Individuals whose home countries’ media is heavily censored have often employed foreign internet services to circulate and read information about what is happening in their country. This weekend’s aborted coup in Turkey demonstrates the importance of foreign platforms to the dissemination of information worldwide. After seeking for years to bring foreign Internet services to heel for circulating information the government disfavored, Turkish President Recep Tayyip Erdoğan found himself turning to Apple’s Facetime to communicate with the world. When the military seized control of local media outlets, Erdogan used Facetime to communicate with CNN Turkey. He didn’t need to find a television studio—where he could have been easily located and imprisoned. As Kieran Healy noted in Vox, “In the past, taking control of the national TV or radio stations would have been enough to eliminate the threat of the leader speaking to the nation, at least for the crucial hours of transition.” The Democratic party is right to see data localization as a threat to both freedom of expression and free trade. Let us hope that both parties can find common ground on this issue.
  • Turkey
    How Many Reserves Does Turkey Need? Some Thoughts on the IMF’s Reserve Metric
    Turkey has long ranked at the top of most lists of financially vulnerable emerging economies, at least lists based on conventional vulnerability measures. Thanks to its combination of a large current account deficit and modest foreign exchange reserves, Turkey has many of the vulnerabilities that gave rise to 1990s-style emerging market crises. Turkey’s external funding need—counting external debts that need to be rolled over—is about 25 percent of GDP, largely because Turkey’s banks have a sizable stock of short-term external debt. At the same time, these vulnerabilities are not new. Turkey has long reminded us that underlying vulnerability doesn’t equal a crisis. For whatever reason, the short-term external debts of Turkey’s banks have tended to be rolled over during times of stress.* And, fortunately, those vulnerabilities have even come down just a bit over the last year or so. After the taper tantrum, Turkey’s banks even have been able to term out some of their external funding by issuing bonds to a yield-starved world in 2014, and by shifting toward slightly longer-term cross-border bank lending in 2015 and 2016 (See figure 4 on pg. 35 of the IMF’s April 2016 Article IV Consultation with Turkey) And while the recent fall in Turkey’s tourism revenue doesn’t look good, Turkey also is a large oil and gas importer. Its external deficit looks significantly better now than it did when oil was above a hundred and Russian gas was more expensive. Turkey doesn’t have many obvious fiscal vulnerabilities; public debt is only about 30 percent of GDP. Its vulnerabilities come from the foreign currency borrowing of its banks and firms. There is one more strange thing about Turkey. Its banks have increased their borrowing from abroad in foreign currency after the global financial crisis, but there hasn’t been comparable growth in domestic foreign currency lending. Rather, the rapid growth has come in lending in Turkish lira, especially to households. So the banks appear to have borrowed abroad and in foreign currency to fund domestic lending in Turkish lira. Bear with me a bit. Balance sheet analysis is interesting but not always straightforward. Turkish banks have significant domestic foreign currency deposits, and lots of domestic foreign currency loans.** The banks have added to their domestic foreign currency funding with a lot of short-term external debt (the data in the chart above sums cross border deposits and "short-term" loans by original maturity). And Turkey’s banks also have lots of liquid foreign currency assets on their balance sheet, some abroad but mostly in the form of deposits at the central bank. When you sum it up, domestic foreign currency deposits cover domestic foreign currency lending. The IMF staff report notes: “The sector’s loan-to-deposit (LtD) ratio stands at 119 percent, with the ratio at 89 and 142 percent for foreign (FX) and local currency respectively.”*** Why then do the Turkish banks borrow in foreign currency abroad, when, on net, they seem to just park the proceeds at the central bank? And how do they finance domestic currency lending with foreign currency borrowing without running an open foreign currency position? Turkey’s banks rely on two bits of financial alchemy. First, the central bank allows the domestic banks to meet much of their reserve requirement (including the reserve requirement on lira deposits) by posting gold and foreign currency at the central bank (this is the famous or infamous reserve option mechanism). That frees up lira to lend domestically.*** And second, the banks clearly rely on “off balance sheet” hedges (cross currency swaps) for a part of their funding. Look at the financial sector section of IMF’s staff report on pp. 23 to 26. The result is an interesting mix of risks. The banks ultimately need wholesale funding in lira, which Turkey’s central bank could supply in extremis—though with consequences for the exchange rate. The banks could also offset a loss of external foreign currency funding by drawing down on their liquid foreign currency assets. Monday’s Central Bank of Turkey (CBRT) press release notes that nearly $50 billion in liquidity sits at the central bank. But if the banks ever needed to draw on their foreign currency reserves, Turkey’s headline reserves would fall fast. A lot of Turkey’s foreign exchange reserves—which are not high to begin with—are effectively borrowed from Turkey’s banks. Makes for an interesting case. And it highlights a second debate of particular interest to me. What role should domestic balance sheet vulnerabilities play in determining the “right” level of foreign currency reserves for an emerging market economy? And what kind of domestic vulnerabilities matter the most, those from domestic currency deposits or those from foreign currency deposits? Specifically, should emerging economies with current account deficits and high levels of domestic liability dollarization (e.g. countries like Turkey) hold more reserves (relative to the size of their economies) than countries with current account surpluses and low levels of domestic liability dollarization (e.g. most East Asian economies, notably China)? This isn’t entirely an academic debate. The IMF’s new reserve metric—a composite indicator that is a weighted average of reserves to short-term external debt, reserves to all external liablities, reserves to exports, and reserves to domestic bank liabilities (M2)—effectively says that countries with large banking systems (like China) need to hold more reserves against the risk of capital flight than countries with heavily liability dollarized banks (like Turkey). And to get all wonky, this is because of the weight the IMF’s reserve index puts on the “M2” variable and the IMF’s decision to omit “foreign currency deposits” from its metric. There turns out to be large variance in the ratio of M2 to GDP across large emerging economies And for those countries, high levels of M2 to GDP are not, in general, correlated with high levels of liability dollarization, while a high level of M2 to GDP, it turns out, is correlated with a current account surplus. Let me be more concrete. M2 to GDP is about 200 percent of GDP in China. It is around 100 percent of GDP in Korea. And about 50 percent of GDP in Turkey. Five percent of M2 (the IMF’s norm for most emerging economies) works out to be roughly 10 percent of GDP in China, 5 percent of GDP in Korea, and 2.5 percent of GDP in Turkey. So there is a meaningful difference across countries. Ten percent of M2—the IMF’s norm for countries with fixed exchanges and open financial accounts—would work out to be about 20 percent of GDP in China. As a result, the M2 (broad money) variable drives much of the variation in the amount of reserves that large emerging economies need to hold to meet the IMF’s reserve norm. the following table, prepared by the CFR’s Emma Smith, decomposes reserve needs at the end of 2015. The IMF also has a somewhat cumbersome reserves data tool here. For countries with high levels of short-term debt and a low level of M2 to GDP, the IMF composite metric can have the effect of reducing the reserves that they need to hold relative to simple measures like reserves to short-term-debt. For example, in December 2015, when Turkey had a bit more short-term debt ($120 billion, by residual maturity) than it does now, the IMF’s metric would have been met with slightly fewer reserves ($115 billion) than Turkey’s short-term external debt. Conversely, for countries with low levels of short-term debt and a high levels of M2 to GDP, the IMF’s metric has the effect of raising needed reserves well above measures based on short-term external debt. China is the most obvious example, but not the only one. Turkey still needs to have a decent amount of reserves relative to the size of its economy to meet the IMF’s metric, especially after the lira’s 2015 depreciation. As it should given its large stock of external debt. I would argue it actually needs even more. $90 billion in foreign exchange reserves is low for a country with lots of foreign currency denominated internal debt (e.g. foreign currency deposits, which fund foreign currency loans) and lots of foreign currency denominated external debt. And I find it a bit strange that with the IMF’s metric China—even with a relatively closed financial account—needs substantially more reserves, relative to the size of its economy, than say Brazil or Russia. Brazil runs a current account deficit and Russia has significant domestic liability dollarization.**** The IMF argues—in its staff guidance note on the reserve metric—that there is no additional risk from high levels of liability dollarization. They didn’t find evidence of more or bigger runs in economies with dollarized liabilities. I am not sure I agree with their interpretation of the data on runs—I remember Uruguay’s crisis, and Ukraine lost substantially more reserves over the past few years than the IMF initially forecast in part because of a draw-down in its domestic foreign currency deposits.***** But more significantly, I would argue that the consequences of a run out of foreign currency deposits are much larger than the consequences of a run out of domestic currency deposits. There is a limit to the ability of most central banks to act as a lender of last resort in foreign currency.****** Technical stuff. But important. It has a big impact on who needs to hold what. * The standard explanation is that some of the funding comes from wealthy Turks with funds offshore. I though wonder if that is still the case given the magnitude of the banks’ external liabilities. ** Turkish firms have increased their foreign currency borrowing from the domestic banks from $50 billion in 2008 to around $180 billion now; the Turkish central bank helpfully provides all the data on this here. The resulting risks are well known. *** See table 6, on p. 44 of the IMF’s staff report for changes in the loan-to-deposit ratio over time. **** See the peer comparison on p 38 of the IMF’s staff report for Turkey, among other sources. ***** See Figure 9, p. 29 of the IMF’s April 2015 paper on reserve adequacy. ****** I tend to compare foreign currency debts to foreign exchange reserves—leaving out gold reserves. I followed that convention in the chart above. I am reconsidering a bit, given Venezuela’s apparent ability to borrow against its gold. But in Turkey’s case, I suspect most of its $20 billion or so in gold is likely borrowed from the banks (through the reserve option mechanism), and thus not really available to meet a foreign currency liquidity need.
  • Turkey
    Turkey Update: Erdogan’s Outlook and the Consequences of the Failed Coup
    Podcast
    CFR's Steven A. Cook discusses the consequences of Turkey's failed coup.
  • Turkey
    Turkey’s in a Terrible Spot
    Geography makes the country a valuable partner for the West. It also makes it vulnerable.
  • Israel
    Israel and Turkey: No Big Deal
    The recent announcement that Israel and Turkey are restoring full diplomatic relations is unlikely to signal the dawn of a new day in Israeli-Turkish relations.
  • Germany
    Merkel’s Erdogan Problem
    Sabina Frizell is a research associate in the Civil Society, Markets, and Democracy Program at the Council on Foreign Relations. This week alone, Turkey jailed two journalists on trumped-up terrorism charges, threatened to sue a professor for insulting President Erdogan, and pushed forward the same construction project that sparked massive anti-government protests in 2013. As Turkey’s democracy deteriorates, German-Turkish relations have gone from tense to outright hostile. Chancellor Angela Merkel is vacillating on whether to hold firm to core European Union (EU) values of democracy and human rights or appease Turkey. She can either continue to waver, tacitly accepting Erdogan’s behavior, or send Turkey a strong signal that its human and civil rights violations are unacceptable. Germany and Turkey are bound by over fifty years of migration. Starting in the 1960s, hundreds of thousands of Turks began immigrating to Germany under its supposedly temporary Gastarbeiter (guest worker) program—but many stayed beyond the intended one-to-two years, bringing their families and settling for good. Today Germany has over three million citizens and residents of Turkish descent, making Turks the country’s largest immigrant group. Amid the ongoing refugee crisis, migration again ties the two countries together. Germany and Turkey were the primary negotiators of the EU-Turkey migrant deal, which set up a one-for-one trade of asylum seekers for Syrian refugees. The EU also pledged €6 billion for Turkey to help settle migrants, and raised the possibility of visa-free travel for Turks. Though widely declared a human rights catastrophe (and rightly so), the deal is critical to Merkel’s already-waning popularity at home—and its success in stemming the flow of migrants hinges on Turkey’s cooperation. As a result, Merkel’s government developed some degree of dependency on Turkey, despite Erdogan’s many affronts to democracy and ever-tightening grip on power. In this context, Germany has at times compromised its own values rather than strain its relationship with Turkey, as in the case of the charges against German comedian Jan Böhmermann. After Böhmermann read a crude poem insulting Erdogan on television, the Turkish government filed a criminal complaint demanding that Germany charge him for violating an archaic German law from the 19th century that prohibits slander of foreign heads of state. Though the law leaves some room for interpretation—it applies to slander, but not satire, riding a fine and subjective line—Merkel approved a criminal prosecution against Böhmermann, and even apologized for the poem. With Turkey extending limitations on free speech beyond its borders, many Germans were outraged, saying Merkel was kowtowing to Erdogan for fear that he might back out of the migrant deal. But the Bundestag has also proved ready to challenge Turkey. This month, the parliament voted almost unanimously to officially recognize the Ottomans’ slaughter of some 1.5 million Armenians during World War I as genocide. Germany follows over twenty countries that have passed similar resolutions, but its voice is especially significant given both its own history, and its complicity with the Armenian genocide as a then ally of the Ottoman Empire (which the resolution acknowledges, calling Germany “partially responsible.”) The Turkish government, which vehemently denies the killings constitute genocide contrary to almost all historical assessments, called Germany’s vote a “test of friendship” and within hours recalled their ambassador to Turkey—warning the move was just a first step. Judging by Turkey’s short memory of other countries’ rulings on the genocide, the threats will likely die down. But the episode nevertheless rattled the countries’ fragile bond. Germany is attempting a precarious balance with Erdogan, and should adopt a more coherent stance—one that recognizes his government’s transgressions consistently, not selectively. To start it should make aid, not just visa-free travel, contingent on Turkish respect for human rights, especially those of the migrants. With a wave of far right parties gaining momentum across Europe and the refugee deal falling apart, Merkel’s center right Christian Democratic Union party may be in jeopardy. Recent polls show support for the bloc is at an all-time low, while distrust of Turkey is rising. Merkel’s ability to manage relations with Ankara will be one crucial piece of maintaining public support.
  • Turkey
    Humanitarian Summit Shines Spotlight on Turkey
    Turkey was selected to host the World Humanitarian Summit in recognition of its generous foreign assistance and refugee policies, but it comes as the country pursues increasingly illiberal policies, says expert Kemal Kirişci.
  • Global
    The World Next Week: May 19, 2016
    Podcast
    Austria holds the second round of presidential elections, Istanbul hosts the World Humanitarian Summit, and U.S. President Barack Obama travels to Vietnam.
  • Emerging Markets
    This Week in Markets and Democracy: Rana Plaza Anniversary, Press Freedom Declines, Haiti Election Troubles
    Labor Standards Three Years After Rana Plaza Three years after Bangladesh’s Rana Plaza garment factory collapse killed or injured over 3,000 people, labor rights remain tenuous. In the wake of the disaster apparel brands, suppliers, and the Bangladeshi government created the Alliance for Bangladesh Worker Safety, a partnership to improve conditions by setting standards and increasing inspections. The Alliance has worked with factories to build emergency exits, install fire hydrants, and rewire electrical systems. It has also blacklisted the worst offenders. Yet it only encompasses those operating under formal contracts. Over half of the nation’s 7,000 factories work in the informal economy. Here, the Bangladeshi government doesn’t enforce Alliance standards, leaving these workers vulnerable. Attacks on the Press Undercut Democracy The world became more difficult and dangerous for journalists in 2015. In Turkey, President Recep Tayyip Erdoğan seized several newspapers and jailed journalists. In Egypt, the government criminalized reporting that contradicts its own information. In Mexico, dozens of cases of murdered reporters remained unsolved. Even in established democracies the press came under attack. In France the government gained new internet and phone surveillance powers, and in Poland the government expanded control over state-owned media. A new Freedom House report finds that only thirteen percent of the world’s population lives in nations with a “free press”—where journalists can report political news without violence, intimidation, or state meddling. This undermining of the fourth estate mirrors that of democracy more generally, which has declined for the tenth consecutive year according to Freedom House. Haiti’s Election Troubles Continue Haiti missed an April 24 deadline to hold its long-delayed presidential runoff election and current political infighting could push a vote off until October. The country’s newly-appointed Provisional Electoral Council (CEP) says it needs more time to verify last year’s first round vote. The United States and others in the international community strongly oppose the delays, citing no evidence of alleged fraud. Haiti’s electoral chaos leaves an interim government in charge as the country faces an El Niño-induced drought and food crisis—its worst in over a decade—affecting over one million Haitian citizens.
  • Turkey
    What to Do About Turkey
    Play
    Experts assess Turkey's relations with its neighbors, as well as its handling of the migrant crisis, and offer U.S. policy options moving forward.