Blogs

Macro and Markets

Kahn analyzes economic policies for an integrated world.

Latest Post

Headquarters of Sberbank, one of the Russian institutions under U.S. sanctions
Headquarters of Sberbank, one of the Russian institutions under U.S. sanctions REUTERS/Sergei Karpukhin

Have Sanctions Become the Swiss Army Knife of U.S. Foreign Policy?

The Congress takes an important, positive step to reinforce Russian sanctions, but are we at risk of overusing the sanctions tool? Read More

Economics
Macri-economics in Argentina
While markets have focused attention on China as the primary source of market risk in 2016, Latin America has provided the more significant headlines in recent weeks.  Political turmoil in Brazil has resulted in the resignation of a market-friendly finance minister, and default looms in Venezuela.  But perhaps nowhere in Latin America is more at stake than with the economic revolution now underway in Argentina. As the first non-Peronist president in more than a decade, Mauricio Macri has promised to roll back populist policies of his predecessors and implement market-friendly measures in Argentina. Following his election, his administration moved quickly to lift currency controls, resulting in a substantial devaluation of the official exchange rate, reduced trade taxes, installed a new central bank president, and raised $5 billion in financing from a group of international banks.  He has also promised to settle the country’s decade long legal battle with creditors, normalizing the country’s economic relations and turning Argentina outward. At a time when populism is constraining economic reform across the industrial and emerging world, many in markets see Argentina as a bright spot in the region. Markets have responded quite positively to this big-bang approach. After dropping over 25 percent, the currency has stabilized and a number of banks have raised their recommendation on Argentine assets. Still, the economic challenge is daunting. Diminishing foreign exchange reserves raise uncertainty in Argentina’s ability to defend peso’s value should crises occur (Figure 1). Inflation is rampant, over 25 percent as of October. The expansionist fiscal policy has also created a deficit that private estimates by companies including Goldman Sachs place between 6 and 7 percent. The sharply weaker currency will exacerbate these challenges, at least temporarily, even as it sets the basis for competitiveness in the longer term.  Without much room to maneuver in collecting revenue, Macri’s fiscal consolidation will most likely rely on cutting expenditure, including popular energy subsidies instituted by his predecessors. Finding alternative sources of expenditure cut and revenue increases will be a difficult though critical task. The broader question is whether this time is different, and whether Argentina can break out of its history of populist economic cycles.  While all these measures are necessary, they will be painful and likely induce economic contraction in the short term. Accustomed to years of economic populism, the Argentine people will now need to support policies previously deeply unpopular. Meanwhile, his party lacks a majority in the Argentine congress. Historically, investors would have done well from buying Argentina after default and selling on efforts at normalization. There’s a danger of political and social backlash, and perhaps this is not the end of populism for Argentina. Against a weak global economic backdrop, the country will face challenging fiscal outlook and likely economic contraction. Getting the sequencing and coordination of reforms right will require a delicate balance between economic change and disruption. Macri’s shock therapy is rare in Latin America, and the track record of shock programs (including notably in post-Soviet Eastern Europe) is mixed. A critical question will be his ability to sustain support until reform produces material improvement in growth prospects. Populist pressure could return quickly if the program falters. There is a lot riding on the outcome.   Figure 1 Source: Central Bank of Argentina
United States
After the Fed
The Federal Reserve today delivered exactly what was expected: a liftoff in interest rates from the zero lower bound, coupled with strong assurances that the future rise in interest rates will be moderate. Markets reacted hardly at all to the statement and Janet Yellen’s press conference, beyond a bit of short covering, by and large seeing the decision as a comforting first step towards normalization at a time of significant global tensions. In sum: The Fed raised the target for the fed funds rate to 0.25 to 0.5 percent, increased the discount rate (the primary credit rate) to 1 percent, slightly revised downward its economic outlook, and released a statement that was comfortably dovish. The participants’ projection for interest rates (“the dots”) suggests perhaps 100 basis points in rate hikes in 2016 and that rates will remain below 3.25 percent through 2018. There also was an implementation note that built on previous releases and explained how the new target will be reached through payment of interest on excess reserves and repo facilities that reflects the detailed preparation that went into the decision and should provide confidence that market liquidity will be smoothly managed. The overall message was that monetary policy will remain extremely accommodative and supportive of a continued economic expansion in the United States. Four broad challenges await though if the Fed is to sustain this optimism. You can’t communicate what you don’t know. The Fed has done a poor job communicating this year, contributing to market volatility and at least temporarily weakening its credibility. In September, for example, within a few days the Fed’s statement, Janet Yellen’s press conference and her speech at the University of Massachusetts arguably provided three different messages about the risks (including importantly international risks) and conditions for liftoff. Adding to the confusion at that time was the perception that the Board was divided on the timing of liftoff, divisions that may well persist with the change in voting members in 2016. But the more fundamental point in the Fed’s defense is that at a time of economic uncertainty, it is hard to credibly precommit to a certain policy path when you are explicitly data dependent. And yet an accommodative policy depends importantly on credible forward guidance on policy. Traditional macroeconomic relationships (e.g., labor market measures and the Phillips curve) have over-predicted inflation in recent years, and there is a substantial debate over whether this represents a temporary or more persistent failure of the models. The current positive pricing in markets reflects a belief that the inflation will remain muted. It doesn’t require an inflation spike, only some evidence that such relationships again have predictive power, to create significant market volatility. A high risk of market turbulence.  It is easy to argue that markets in 2016 will face higher policy and geopolitical risks than they have for some time: China, emerging markets, and populism and anti-union pressures in Europe to name a few. As many have noted, the beginning of Fed normalization at a time when the European Central Bank (ECB) and Bank of Japan are still easing introduces a period of policy asynchronization that traditionally is associated with greater market volatility, especially for exchange rates. Emerging markets remain a central concern. There is growing concern about growth and financial fragility risks in emerging markets, against which continuing capital outflows creates an additional global uncertainty.  The Fed has made clear in recent months that international uncertainties have weighed on their decision making (though expressing confidence that those shocks would have a lessening effect on U.S. activity over time), and Janet Yellen’s press conference comments emphasized her commitment to communicate carefully their plans to avoid spillovers to other markets. I do not believe that there is a credible argument that the Fed has under-accounted for these external risks. Still, this may be the major uncertainty for the outlook. End of an era?  Since the start of the Great Recession, monetary policy has carried most of the burden of support for economic activity. Now that is coming to an end, reflecting not only the Fed’s decision but also a growing skepticism about the power that successive rounds of quantitative easing programs have on industrial economies. An increase in interest rates does provide some scope for rates to be lowered in the face of future adverse shocks, but the benefit of returning to zero is limited. One does not have to fully subscribe to secular stagnation theories to believe that fiscal and structural policies will need to take more responsibility for growth in the period ahead.
International Organizations
IMF Reform Moves Forward
There are reports this morning that House and Senate legislators have included language authorizing U.S. support for International Monetary Fund (IMF) reform in the $1.1 trillion spending package funding the government for the rest of FY16.  If this language reaches the president’s desk and is signed into law, it would be an important achievement and a positive reflection on the perseverance of U.S Treasury officials and congressional leaders to get this deal done. The package—first agreed to by the Obama administration in 2010—changes voting shares and governance for the institution at a critical time, bolstering the IMF’s credibility and its ability to play a lead firefighting role at times of crisis.  Failure to pass the legislation had become a substantial irritant for U.S. influence internationally, and resolving this is a win for good global economic governance. The price the administration paid included a commitment to seek to eliminate the “Systemic Exemption”, the rule that since 2010 has allowed lending even when there was a risk that the debt was unsustainable, and that was used to support loans for the periphery countries of Europe.  I have supported the rule, which recognizes the inevitable risk involved in these large scale programs where there are broad systemic effects, but giving up the rule is a small price to pay to get IMF reform passed. Should a global crisis threaten in the future, the IMF may again need to bend their rules to respond effectively. That discussion now will begin with a clean sheet of paper, and Congress will need to be informed. The administration also has promised to report to the Congress ahead of any vote supporting a large lending program.  While these commitments add an extra layer of process, I agree with others that requiring clear explanations before and after the use of such a policy can strengthen the legitimacy of such policy decisions. The idea for this trade--IMF reform for the Systemic Exemption--originates with John Taylor, and I gave it a strong endorsement when I testified before the Senate Foreign Relations Committee earlier this year. Quietly, as a footnote to the broader budget deal, good policy is being made.
  • Europe
    Addressing Economic Populism in Europe
    My latest global economic monthly looks at rising economic populism in Europe and how it constrains the capacity of policymakers to get a robust recovery going and deal with shocks. Some of the drivers of populism—on the left and right, in creditor and debtor countries—are cyclical but many including globalization, income inequality and insecurity are likely to be more persistent and resent a long-term threat to greater European integration. The strong showing of the National Front in last weekend’s French regional elections, Denmark’s referendum rejection of further EU integration, and Britain’s debate over its EU future are recent reminders of the fraying consensus on further integration, which has strong implications for economic cooperation. Easy money from the European Central Bank (ECB) can only do so much, and a broader policy response including a faster pace of economic integration and more flexible fiscal policies now are needed.
  • Budget, Debt, and Deficits
    Ukraine’s Decisive Moment
    Budget debates are often dry affairs, but not so in Kiev. By the end of this month, the Ukrainian parliament (Verkhovna Rada) must decide on a budget that will have profound effects on the future course of the government. The Ministry of Finance has proposed a budget that sets most tax rates at 20 percent, while closing loopholes and holding the deficit to an estimated 3.7 percent of GDP.  The International Monetary Fund (IMF) has endorsed the plan, and the passage of the bill, or something close to it, is essential to completing the IMF review and keeping the government’s adjustment program on track. An alternative plan, which is supported by the opposition and, disappointingly, by elements of President Poroshenko’s own party, involves a massive tax cut that would reduce rates to a flat rate of 10 percent, causing the deficit to soar to over 10 percent of GDP. A continued IMF role would be ruled out. Following a deep recession from which Ukraine is just starting to recover, populist fiscal policy promising quick fixes understandably is attractive, and opponents of the government may well believe that the government can do it alone without foreign financing (and, importantly, without the rule of law reforms that form the core of the government’s IMF-backed program). But it would be a tremendous mistake. It’s important to remember how much has been achieved by this government on the economic front. Against the backdrop of war and a historic political transition, the economic team has carried forward a difficult and ambitious adjustment program. After a fall of GDP of around 20 percent, the economy has stabilized, fiscal deficits have been slashed to levels consistent with available domestic and external financing, and a deep restructuring of the banking sector has been launched. Perhaps more importantly, significant structural reforms have been enacted including hikes in energy prices and a comprehensive rewriting of the legal framework underpinning the economy. Recently, a broad debt restructuring was completed that provides over $15 billion in cash flow relief over the next three years, as well as a modest reduction in principal. Russia refused to participate and restructure a $3 billion bond due in December, but later this week the IMF Board will meet and agree to a policy change that will allow Ukraine’s IMF program to proceed even if the bond is not paid. Unfortunately, the program has faltered in some important aspects. The move against corruption has stalled in recent months, raising serious concerns among Ukraine’s allies whether vested interests were reasserting themselves. Rule of law reforms are central to the IMF program and critical to any effort to break from the past decades of corruption and poor economic performance. But the implementation of these reforms (including paying adequate salaries) is costly. Further, without a sound macroeconomic framework, it will be increasingly hard to sustain popular support for this reform effort. A sound budget is a gateway test for any serious reform effort. Vice President Biden is in Kiev and will speak to the Rada tomorrow. He is expected to deliver a tough measure on the need for Ukraine to jumpstart the reform process, particularly the anti-corruption agenda, and will also promise additional U.S. assistance. This message, which was foreshadowed and endorsed by my colleague Stephen Sestanovich, includes a strong case for an attack on corruption but there also needs to be a stepping up of financial support for the government to allow for a budget that can support the reform effort and enhance security. A grand bargain is urgently needed. The Ukraine government needs to jumpstart the implementation of rule of law, judiciary and civil service  reforms and take on vested interests. President Poroshenko must come out and fully endorse the Ministry of Finance proposal (and his finance minister Natalie Jaresko), and then whip the votes needed to get it passed.  And Western governments must provide more bilateral assistance so that Ukrainians can have confidence that the program can succeed and restore growth. Ukraine should not go back.