Blogs

Macro and Markets

Kahn analyzes economic policies for an integrated world.

Latest Post

Headquarters of Sberbank, one of the Russian institutions under U.S. sanctions
Headquarters of Sberbank, one of the Russian institutions under U.S. sanctions REUTERS/Sergei Karpukhin

Have Sanctions Become the Swiss Army Knife of U.S. Foreign Policy?

The Congress takes an important, positive step to reinforce Russian sanctions, but are we at risk of overusing the sanctions tool?

Read More
Europe
Sour on Europe
The most recent Pew Survey on European attitudes (summary table below) shows that support for the European integration project is dropping.  My colleagues at CFR are far more able than I am to address the broader political ramifications of this shift.  A few points though on the link between economic growth, public opinion, and support for the European reform agenda. Growth matters.  Today’s Eurozone GDP numbers remind us that Europe remains in a grinding recession; a second-half recovery now looks to be a long shot at best.  The only bright spot comes elsewhere, with news of  a German labor deal that will raise engineering wages by nearly 6 percent over the next 20 months (rebalancing European demand and stimulating German consumption needs more of this).  Some of the decline in the Pew numbers likely is cyclical, as declining confidence in their own economic prospects seems to spill over to other issues.  Notably, the need for jobs dominates other issues on the economic agenda.  The mood is particularly bleak in the periphery, reflecting those countries’ economic troubles. This is consistent with the idea the recession and diminishing expectations for the recovery are weighing materially on public opinion. A disillusioned France should matter to markets.  The sharpest decline in sentiment in the survey--both for their own economic prospects and for the EU project--is in France.  This coincides with other reporting suggesting declining confidence in the government’s ability to put the economy on the right track.  In this regard, markets could be sensitive to a rise in opposition to the European project in France.  The right-wing National Front (FN) party headed by Marine Le Pen has announced that it will run in next May’s EU parliamentary elections on a platform calling for an referendum on the euro.  How would markets react if--fueled by disillusionment with the government’s economic program--the FN was the first past the post in those elections? Will a single chart damage Europe’s efforts to resolve the crisis?  I missed this when it first came out, but it’s still worth a look.  Last month, the ECB’s Eurosystem Household Finance and Consumption Survey presented estimates, for households, of median net wealth and the median value of their main residence.  The interesting datapoint:  Germany is at the bottom.  Belgium, Spain and Italy (and, yes, Cyprus) all have household wealth several times German levels. When this was released last month, the German press had a field day with the message that Germany shouldn’t bail out rich southern Europeans.  There was pushback:  it was noted that if means rather than medians were used, Germany would be in the middle of the pack (reflecting a more skewed German income distribution).  Further, the high proportion of renting rather than buying homes in Germany means more housing wealth is off the household balance sheet.  Broader measures of national wealth, including capital, restore Germany to the top ranks in terms of income. The Pew survey (taken before the release of the chart), conversely shows Germans still support the European project, and are willing to pay to support it.  (By 52 percent to 45 percent, Germans support bailouts for countries in crisis, compared to 40 percent in favor in France.)  It remains to be seen, though, whether the chart below and the pessimism reflected in the Pew Survey resonates with less affluent German voters already suffering from bailout fatigue.  
Europe
The Unapologetic Regulator
Jaret Seiberg has an excellent summary of Ben Bernanke’s speech and Q&A today on financial sector regulation and reform.  This follows on Dan Tarullo’s speech Friday that highlighted the need for additional capital aginst short-term wholesale funding, an earlier Jeremy Stein discussion on liquidity regulation and the value of price-based regulation (rather than quantitiative limits on bank size favored by some in Congress), and similar comments by the OCC.  We now have as clear a signal as possible that U.S. regulators are ready, in Seiberg’s words, "to go beyond Basel 3 to impose to additional capital requirements on the biggest banks...[using]...a combination of a more restrictive leverage limit, a capital surcharge based on reliance on short-term debt, and a long-term debt requirement." It also underscores the divergent approaches toward reform in the U.S. and Europe, where, against the backdrop of weak growth and credit constraints, the pressures appear to be leading to a slower, more bank-friendly path.
United States
The Shrinking U.S. Labor Force and Fed Policy
Does the large drop in the U.S. labor force participation rate justify a monetary policy that is easier, for longer, than suggested by our models or the Fed’s current description of its policy?  Chris Erceg and Andy Levin, two senior researchers at the Fed now on leave at the IMF, argue yes.  Their analysis will provide fuel to the monetary policy doves who argue the Fed is failing to meet its employment mandate, and points to a battle ahead.  But it doesn’t really settle questions about whether monetary policy is an effective tool for bringing these workers back into the work force, or whether it can be done without creating inflationary pressure (which speaks to other leg of the Fed’s mandate). Still, their paper is an important read. The unexplained fall in labor force participation Their first chart shows the decline in labor force participation since 2007, both in absolute terms and relative to a Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) forecast for the future path of the participation rate made in 2007.  It suggests that the sharp drop in the participation rate since 2007 was unexpected and hard to explain by the structural factors that affected participation in the past such as the aging of the population, or shifts in specific groups such as female or youth workers.  This means that the gap between the two lines, the "participation gap," must be cyclical--the result of the great recession--or because of some new structural factors that the BLS didn’t anticipate.   The structural argument deserves some elaboration.  Recall that labor force participation actually peaked around 2000 and was on a downtrend even before the great recession (see next chart). One view is that this means there are even more "missing workers" put out of jobs, involuntarily, by the weak recovery of 2000-07.  I think a better explanation is that there were already structural changes underway in the workforce that are not captured by the BLS forecast.  From this perspective, the great recession is an accelerant that forces change (eg, in terms of labor-saving by firms, changes in long-term competitiveness, or changes demand for skills) that had been building already.  Whether you want to describe this as cyclical or structural, these workers may not be easily brought back into the labor force through expansionary macro policies.   Civilian Labor Force Participation Rate, 16 and older Source: BLS This next chart from Erceg and Levin shows that the participation gap (derived from the first chart)-- the orange dotted line--now exceeds the gap between current unemployment and the long-run unemployment rate (the purple line).  It shows that the participation rate adjusts more slowly than the unemployment rate.  It also highlights the amount of slack that needs to be absorbed is potentially much larger than suggested by the unemployment rate alone. The bulk of the Erceg and Levin paper then addresses two critical questions:  Is this structural or cyclical? And will it persist as the economy recovers (and the unemployment rate drops)?  On the question of cyclicality, the paper looks at a cross-section of state participation rates during the recession (see below).  States with the deepest recessions had the sharpest fall in unemployment, which they argue suggests it’s weak demand that is driving much of the recent decline in participation.  State data has been criticized in the past as subject to noise and error, and others suggest that looking at flows into and out of the labor force is more consistent with a structural explanation.  In any event, this result is central to the debate over whether ’this time is different’ because the post-war experience has been that participation is largely non-cyclical. The Fed’s employment mandate "The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and the Federal Open Market Committee shall maintain long run growth of the monetary and credit aggregates commensurate with the economy’s long run potential to increase production, so as to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices and moderate long-term interest rates." (Federal Reserve Act, 1977) The Fed is unusual among central banks in having a statutory dual mandate to ensure both maximum employment and stable prices.  The Fed has long stressed that in most circumstances these two objectives are consistent, and further that it looks at a wide array of indicators in fulfilling its mandate.  However, much economic theory, and the Fed itself, have put the spotlight on the unemployment rate (and its relationship to the longer run, normal rate of unemployment) as the most important single metric of labor conditions.  This focus has intensified since the Fed, in December 2012, announced that an unemployment rate of 6.5 percent would serve as a threshold (not a trigger) for tightening policy from the current near-zero levels. The dilemma for the FOMC is how to react if the unemployment rate declines to below 6.5 percent while the participation rate remains low.  Should we look at the sum of the unemployment and participation gaps as the measure Fed policy must address?  In assessing this argument, the Fed will have to answer three questions in particular: How low can the unemployment rate go before inflationary pressures emerge? The Fed’s estimates of the central tendency for the longer-run, normal unemployment rate, at 5.2-6 percent, is substantially higher than they forecast several years ago, reminding us of the inherent uncertainty in these traditional macro relationships. Does a high participation gap put downward pressure on inflation?  Certainly inflationary pressures remain muted, even too low (recent work by Lars Svensson and others suggest inflation below 1 percent can be distortionary and undermine a credible central bank’s policy).  But the great recession also has undermined notions of a tight relationship between slack in the economy and inflation (inflationary expectations haven’t moved very much with the recession) suggesting the need for caution during the upturn as well.  Does the existence of a pool of workers that have left the workforce, for example to retire or to go to school because there are limited job opportunities, put downward pressure on the wages of those who have jobs? Is monetary policy the right tool to address the participation gap? Recent research on long-term unemployment suggests that, once workers are unemployed more than six months, their connection to the work force become tenuous.  In such cases, even if their exit was the result of a demand shock, at some point they lose the skills, the connectivity, and the resume to reenter easily. What starts as cyclical becomes structural.  Monetary policy may be a blunt tool for addressing the participation gap, suggesting targeted fiscal policies (e.g., job retraining and employment subsidies) may be more effective tools.  The monetary policy dove will argue that absent fiscal policy, monetary policy is the best tool in the toolbox, while critics will weigh these potentially modest benefits against the cost of an even larger balance sheet. None of these questions have easy answers. Erceg and Levin are careful to emphasize the limits of their analysis.  But their work, and the notion that the Fed needs to target policy to reduce this gap, may be front and center at future FOMC meetings.
  • Budget, Debt, and Deficits
    U.S. Debt Ceiling: A Plan to Kick the Can?
    House Republicans want to tie an increase in the debt ceiling due in September/October to a concrete process for corporate tax reform, as reported here and here.  One idea is to couple  a short-term debt limit increase to a mandate for the House to pass a tax-reform plan. The debt limit would increase further when the House passes its plan, and again when the Senate passes a plan. Corporate tax reform (and its possible link to the debt limit) will be in the spotlight this week as the Joint Committee on Taxation today is expected to release recommendations compiled by 11 House Ways & Means working groups. Jaret Seiberg at Guggenheim highlights the possiblity of market-relevant headlines on the mortgage interest deduction, the corporate debt deduction, the tax treatment for REITs and master limited partnerships (MLPs), and overall corporate tax rates.  Meanwhile, the House likely will pass a bill this week calling on the U.S. Treasury to prioritize payments, an authority many believe that they already have (and which the Senate will not move on).  As we move forward, these two issues will be increasingly linked. Better-than-expected fiscal numbers, and the prospect of a one-time transfer from the government sponsored enterprises (GSEs), have pushed back the date when the debt limit (to be reset to the level of indebtedness on May 19) is expected to bite starting in July/August until the fall.  The deficit now is running at a 4.5 percent of GDP pace, well down from 10.1 percent in fiscal year 2010.  With the effects of the sequester beginning to build, this dramatic fiscal tightening looks to subtract around 2 percent of GDP from growth this year.  Too much, too fast from a macroeconomic perspective, but good news on the debt-limit front. Does this possible link of corporate-tax reform to the debt ceiling materially increase the prospect of new legislation in the near term?  Certainly the committee chairs are motivated and have laid out their core reform principles. I remain skeptical that we can have a grand bargain that overcomes the vast differences between the positions of the two sides (e.g., different stances on top rates, revenue, and treatment of foreign source income).  This proposal, if implemented, would likely lead to gridlock in committee once each house has passed a bill.  But the advantage of linking debt-ceiling increases to corporate tax reform would be that even if the process ultimately fails to deliver, it could still push the debt limit past the midterm elections.  That’s a very small prize, but perhaps the best alternative to another cliff showdown, as there is little evidence of a plan B both sides could sign on to.
  • Europe
    Rogoff and Reinhart on Austerity
    Ken Rogoff and Carmen Reinhart (R&R) have a good piece in the Financial Times today, "Austerity is not the only answer to a debt problem." This, along with other pieces (for example, here and here), is moving the debate over their work in the right direction. On the one hand, recognition that debt still matters, and too much debt (whether the result of or the cause of low growth) is damaging to our politics and our economics. On the other hand, rejection of the idea that there is a universal growth "cliff" when debt exceeds 90 percent of GDP that is at work across countries (an idea their earlier work promoted, unfortunately).  R&R go on to argue that while fixing our debt problem is a central challenge, that doesn’t mean we need aggressive austerity today (though additional stimulus needs to be carefully decided on). The implications are not only domestic. As Richard Haass notes in Foreign Policy Begins at Home: The Case for Putting America’s House in Order, putting our own house in order is essential to an effective foreign policy as well. R&R’s comments on European debt also deserve note: "For Europe, in particular, any reasonable endgame will require a large transfer from Germany to the periphery. The sooner this implicit transfer becomes explicit, the sooner Europe will be able to find its way towards a stable growth path."  Those who read this blog know I agree strongly with this statement, and believe that we have a model already in place--the Paris Club--that provides a way forward.  Perhaps after the German elections we will get an open discussion of the need for official debt relief before another crisis hits, but I’m not optimistic.