2007 has been a lot better than 2005 for the dollar bears …
from Follow the Money

2007 has been a lot better than 2005 for the dollar bears …

More on:

Financial Markets

Some no doubt will take a revival of interest in a set of 2004 and 2005 papers (Rogoff-ObstfeldKrugman, Roubini-Setser, no doubt others) arguing that a real depreciation in the dollar is needed to correct the trade deficit as a clear sign that the dollar is over-sold and due for a rally. 

However, the dollar's fall isn't just a late 2007 story -- or even a post 50 bp Fed cut story.  The dollar has been sliding pretty steadily against the euro since early 2006. 

And there is good reason, at least in view, to expect broad dollar weakness to persist for some time.   While the dollar quite weak against the major currencies, it isn't that weak relative to the emerging world.  The broad dollar only just returned to its 1996 level.  Sustained adjustment likely requires that the dollar fall a bit below that level.

So what is different from say late 2004, when there last was a burst of concern about the dollar? 

The current account deficit – at least in the past few quarters – is roughly the same share of US GDP as it was in late 2004.    But that masks one important difference: in 2004, the deficit was growing, while right now the US trade deficit – at least the non-oil trade deficit – is falling. 

It will be interesting to see if sustained $80 a barrel oil offsets the improvement in the non-oil balance in the tail end of q3 and in q4.  A $1 increase in the price of oil over the course of the year increases the US oil import bill by about $5b – so there is a big difference between the $60 a barrel average price for sweet light crude in q1 and the $75 average in q3.  

However, there is no question that the bilateral deficit with Europe is falling particularly quickly.   Back in 2004, an economist at a large German auto maker indicated that, given productivity differentials between the firm’s German and US plants, it only really made sense for German car makers to produce in the US if the euro was above 1.3.   I don’t think it is an accident that the Germans are starting to rev up their US production while the ratio of Japanese cars manufactured in the US relative to Japanese cars sold in the US continues to slide … 

The fall in the non-oil trade deficit though isn't a dollar positive -- not when the trade deficit is falling because the US is growing less rapidly than the rest of the world.   That undercuts the attractiveness of US financial assets.   Throw in the fact that the United States supposed comparative advantage in financial securitization technology doesn't seem like much of an advantage right now -- no one currently is willing to pay a premium for a CDO stuffed with tranches of US subprime mortgage-backed securities – and there isn't sufficient private demand for US assets to cover the US deficit.  

The official sector doesn't finance the US because it particularly wants to; it finances the US because a number of countries still prefer financing the US to letting their currencies appreciate.That is actually rather similar to 2004 -- particularly the fourth quarter of 2004 when intervention by emerging economies spiked up. 

But  there is another key difference.   Right now, the interest rate differential isn’t moving in the dollar’s favor.  David Woo of Barclay’s Capital thinks the US/ Euro rates differential is already too small to lend much support to the dollar.  And if the Fed continues to cut and the ECB doesn't, well --  the interest rate differential might turn against the dollar.   The Homeland Investment Act isn’t poised to generate a $200b capital inflow (and a boost to the dollar, as some funds held offshore weren’t in dollars) in 2008.    The trigger for renewed private demand for dollars isn't obvious. 

Ken Rogoff provides another reason to expect dollar weakness to persist: the slowdown in US productivity growth.   That makes sense.   

I am not sure, though, that the post 2002 expansion ever really stemmed from strong US productivity growth relative to the rest of the world.   If strong productivity growth is pulling in capital, foreign investors presumably would want to be buying US equities rather than buying US bonds -- as Martin Wolf likes to note, bonds don't obviously benefit from faster growth.   Moreover, the counterpart to the expansion of the US deficit hasn’t been a rise in the surplus of those regions of the world with slow productivity growth.   Rather the contrary.  Chinese productivity growth has long put US productivity growth to shame.   The global counterpart to the rise in the US deficit was a rise in the emerging world's surplus, and it is a little hard to see how differentials in productivity growth explain the rise in the US deficit with the fast-growing emerging world.  That makes the post-2002 expansion of the trade deficit all the more puzzling.

I would note one additional change: a likely shift in the currency composition of the portfolio of the world's large oil exporters.   Qatar (hat tip Macro man) recently indicated that it cut the dollar share of its investment authority’s portfolio to around 40% . Kuwait has also reduced the dollar share of its portfolio.   Russia cut the dollar share of its reserves from around 70% to around 50%.    Pretty soon the Saudis will be the only big oil exporter keeping the majority of their assets in dollars ...   

Ramin Toloui calculates that the oil exporters need to keep around 60% of their assets in dollars for a rise in oil prices to be dollar positive.   They probably aren’t doing that.  More spending and investment in the oil-exporting economies also isn't a dollar positive: the dollar's share of the oil-exporting economies financial portfolio certainly tops the United States share of their import portfolio.

Incidentally, there seems to be new interest in a paper I wrote earlier this year  for the Peterson institute on oil and global adjustment.   It doesn't focus explicitly on the oil/ dollar link: I wasn’t as convinced then as I am now that the GCC investment funds had cut the dollar share of their portfolio.  But it does provide at least one way of thinking about how higher oil prices will influence the global flow of funds.   

All this said, the 2004 Roubini-Setser paper on the US as a net debtor clearly got two key things wrong.

First, it argued that the net international investment position (NIIP) of the US and the income balance were both poised to deteriorate significantly.   Neither has happened.   One of the arguments for why the NIIP would deteriorate was that the dollar wasn’t going to fall against the euro at the same pace as in 2003, so there would be smaller valuation gains going forward.   We didn’t anticipate the outperformance of European equities relative to US equity markets would deliver valuation gains even in the absence of a big fall in the dollar (remember the end 2004 “valuation” for US investment in Europe was based on an exchange rate of 1.35 or so, so even a dollar at 1.41 doesn’t produce big valuation gains).   

The willingness of foreigners to finance the US even as US markets under perform markets abroad is a real puzzle – one only partially explained by the actions of the world central banks.   Those central banks that reduced the dollar share of their reserves back in 2004, 2005 and 2006 have done better than those that didn’t.    

The other puzzle is the persistence of the United States’ positive income balance.   I still expect the income balance to deteriorate – and for the deterioration in the income balance to offset some of the improvement in the trade balance.   But that deterioration hasn't happened yet.   That though is a topic for another time.

Second, the 2004 paper argued that the world’s central banks wouldn’t continue to finance an expansion of the US current account deficit – and a lack of financing in turn risked causing a slowdown in the US economy to slow.   The casual relationship actually seems to have been the opposite.  The US economy slowed because of an overbuilt housing sector (particularly given limited median real wage growth) rather than because of a shortage of foreign financing. 

This though matters far more for the path of US interest rates than for the path of the dollar.    Central banks stop financing the US?  Long-term rates rise and the dollar falls.    The US slows on its own?   Long-term rates fall and the dollar falls. 

The 2004 paper was generally taken to be an argument to sell the dollar against the euro.  But fundamentally it argued that the dollar was far more over-valued against the emerging world than against Europe – and as a result the dollar really needed to depreciate against emerging market currencies.  Implicitly, that was an argument that the euro would weaken as well – not against the dollar, but against the emerging world.

And that hasn’t happened.    The same pressures that pushed the dollar down against the euro are present elsewhere.   But that pressure shows up in the reserves data far more than in the exchange rate.   Consider the following chart:

em_reserves__euro
 

By now though, you can make a reasonable case that the pace of emerging market reserve growth has reached the point where its costs exceed any reasonable estimate of its benefits – which suggests that emerging economies might begin to allow their currencies to appreciate.

But a lot are not perched on such a steep gradient that they cannot let go of the brake without really zooming downhill (or perhaps uphill – as they would rise, but then the metaphor doesn’t really work).   A controlled descent on a very steep gradient requires using the brakes.   And in this case, the only brake in the system – barring a surge in private demand for dollar assets – is emerging market central banks’ willingness to increase their reserves to control the pace of appreciation of their currencies. 

To stretch the metaphor a bit more, a dollar plunge could happen in one of two ways – if emerging market central banks decided to stop using the brake of intervention to control the dollar’s descent, or if they burn out the brakes trying to control the descent.    The gradient is now so steep that I would be very surprised if emerging market central banks didn’t try to use the brake – but the road down is now long and steep enough that the odds that the brakes might burn out has increased.

Stephen King – of HSBC – seems to be getting increasingly worried that emerging economies might conclude that it no longer is in their interest to prop up the dollar, or to use my earlier metaphor, that the inflationary heat from trying to control the pace of the dollar's descent through central bank intervention may prompt policy change.

Falling US interest rates would make the control of inflation even more difficult within the emerging world, eventually increasing the temptation to "go it alone" and leave the dollar to its own destiny. Might this lead to a dollar collapse, a loss of US monetary credibility and the end of an economic pax Americana?

Perhaps this is a fairy-tale too far. I sense, though, that recent events are not a one-off ... Instead, the story unfolding is one full of sub-plots, geographical intricacies and economic dependencies. It may finish happily ever after. But it might, instead, end up like one of those novels from my namesake, a horrific mixture of weak growth, sticky inflation and, ultimately, a loss of confidence in the dollar's status as a reserve currency.

Ken Rogoff suggests that that time has come for those gathering in Washington in a couple of weeks to engineer a revaluation of the currencies of the major surplus regions of the world economy.   Among other things, so long as the dollar and the euro hold stable, an appreciation against the dollar by the emerging world would also lead to an appreciation against the euro.  That would make "euro strength" against the dollar easier to bear.   

I agree.

I don't think there is much doubt that the costs of pegging to the dollar and the resulting need to accumulate dollar reserves are becoming increasingly visible throughout much of the emerging world.    Both the US and Europe would benefit if the emerging world allowed their currencies to appreciate a bit more rapdily against the dollar; the currencies of booming China and the Gulf shouldn't be depreciating along with the dollar right now.  At the same time, the US is counting on the emerging world to intervene enough control the pace of the dollar’s descent  ...

More on:

Financial Markets