• Europe
    Eurogroup statement on Greece
    Here it is (via the Guardian): "The Eurogroup broadly welcomed a new version of the reform plan submitted by the Greek authorities this morning, before the Eurogroup meeting, and considered it to be a positive step in the process. The Eurogroup asked the institutions (the European Commission, the European Central Bank and the International Monetary Fund) to start analysing the new proposal and together with the Greek authorities work out a list of prior actions with a view to reaching a final agreement on the reform plan later this week. The Eurogroup might hold another meeting this week. " It is hard to be optimistic about this: the emphasis on “prior actions” highlights the lack of trust between the sides and means that Greek “red lines” will need to be crossed before it receives cash. That is a high hurdle.
  • Europe
    Greece: Still No Deal
    European finance ministers met earlier today and afterwards stated that new proposals from the Greek government were "broadly comprehensive" and "a solid basis" for restarting talks, but made clear that the Greek plan was far from complete and received too late for a deal to be concluded today. Markets had rallied earlier on hopes of a deal. But they fell back on comments from German Finance Minister Wolfgang Schauble and others who saw little new in the Greek proposal, suggesting significant splits among creditors. Leaders meet this evening, but it now appears that critical decisions will wait for the next finance ministers’ gathering, likely Thursday. Separately, the European Central Bank’s (ECB) board again expanded emergency assistance by 2 billion euros to Greek banks after weekend ATM withdrawals and orders for today reportedly exceeded 1.4 billion euros. With today’s modestly constructive statements though, it will be difficult for the ECB to cut off access to Greek banks over the next few days even in the face of broad insolvency in the Greek financial system. The new Greek proposal reportedly includes concessions on the value added tax (VAT) and a small move to limit the early retirement schemes that are a major contributor to the pension deficit. There appears to be broad consensus among creditors—if there is a deal—to provide financing to cover upcoming debt maturities, and they have signaled their willingness to commit to debt restructuring if Greece adheres to the program. But there appear to be many gaps in the Greek proposal, and a lot that can go wrong over the next few days. I would also expect pressure to mount on Prime Minister Alexis Tsipras back home.  Already, minority coalition partner ANEL said cutting the 30 percent VAT discount for the Greek islands, one of the most egregious examples of fiscal excess, would be reason to leave the government. It is also worth commenting on the dynamic between finance ministers and leaders. One recurring feature of the European crisis negotiations of the past several years is the desire of finance ministers to prevent their leaders from giving away too much to get last minute deals.  Consequently, even if the aim is to encourage negotiations, ministers will be wary to suggest a deal is close and will insist that negotiations remain with them. Negative comments from Finance Minister Schauble and others need to be interpreted in that light, and are likely to successfully dampen any hopes for a breakthrough at the leaders’ summit tonight. We will need to wait for more details on the Greek proposal.  If there is to be a deal, we know what it should look like to generate sustained Greek growth within the eurozone. But it is hard to be more optimistic this morning that the parties are closer to concluding such a deal.  The IMF in particular is likely to be quite disappointed with where negotiations seem to be headed. I share that concern, and fear that any deal being discussed is a "bridge to nowhere".  The risks of banking controls and default appear to remain high.
  • Europe
    Greece: Banking on Controls
    It is time for banking controls in Greece. Delay at this point will only compound the chaos. Consider the following. Thursday’s meeting of Euro-area finance ministers made no progress toward a deal. That was not surprising. What was more noticeable was the discord that followed. IMF Managing Director Christine Lagarde summed it up: for a Greek deal to happen, there will have to be “adults in the room”. There will now be an emergency leader’s summit on Monday, but absent a major U-turn by the Greek government, that meeting is likely to turn to a discussion of “plan b.” Against this backdrop, there has been a rapid acceleration in outflows from the banking system, reportedly in excess of €2bn in the first three days of week. Deposit flight likely will intensify tomorrow and Monday. The ECB will hold an emergency phone call this morning to decide whether to expand emergency assistance (ELA) to the Greek banking system from its current limit of €81 billion. To keep the banks open, the ECB will need to provide a significant injection of liquidity. They should not do it. Greek banks are clearly insolvent. The crisis has caused a spike in non-performing loans, the economy is deteriorating rapidly, and with the Greek government on the verge of default to the IMF, the ECB can no longer pretend that the Greek government bonds that the banks have provided as collateral for past loans are adequate protection against loss. (Arrears to the IMF do not force other creditors’ claims into default, but the political statement of non-cooperation would be powerful unless serious negotiations are underway.) Further, ready access to central bank liquidity has disabled an important source of market discipline on the government, throws good money after bad, and creditor frustration with the continuing demands for financing make the politics of a deal all the more challenging. The Greek government is likely to resist imposing banking controls, but absent an agreement with creditors controls on deposit withdrawals and cross-border transfers look unavoidable once ECB liquidity support has been curtailed. Controls will buy some time for the government, but how much is unclear. The immediate challenge is fiscal and domestic. The government reported a sharp fall in fiscal revenue last month, reflecting a declining economy and substantial tax non-compliance. In response, it has slashed spending and delayed payments to suppliers and contractors. But large-scale arrears are causing significant payments difficulties in the broader economy, and are not sustainable for long when banks can’t lend. For this reason, I am skeptical that the government can sustain deficit spending for long through creation of IOUs, a informal secondary currency within Greece. How the government responds to these fiscal challenges will go a long way to determining whether controls are a way station to Grexit or, as elsewhere (e.g., Cyprus), breathing space to restructure and adjust within the currency union. My colleague Sebastian Mallaby has an excellent discussion of the perils for Greece of heading down this path, and he makes a convincing case that Grexit is not an easy option. The converse is also true. The international community has coalesced around the policies needed to put Greece on a sustainable path within the Eurozone. That includes additional debt relief and perhaps as much as 2 percentage points of GDP in new measures this year alone—including to pensions, wages, and taxes—measures that the Greek government has firmly rejected and that would be a major economic and political challenge to pass and implement. If Greece were to accept the deal, Europe would need to provide additional debt relief to make the numbers add up, a point recently emphasized by the IMF. Tough decisions are called for on both sides, and the prospect for bridging this gap is looking increasingly remote. While the temptation thus exists to buy time by extending the current program, trading cash for partial reforms, and putting off negotiations on a third bailout until the fall, it is a “bridge to nowhere” if it doesn’t put Greece on a credible path back to sustainable growth.            
  • Europe
    Greece’s Bridge to Nowhere
    Negotiations continue today between Greece and its creditors, with reports that the government has presented a revised proposal that offers minor concessions in an effort to break the deadlock. A deal is needed in the next week if a package of assistance is to be put in place before end-month payments of $1.7 billion are due to the IMF. While this is not a hard deadline—a short-term default to the IMF need not sink the Greek economy—the government is out of cash and it is hard to imagine how they make critical domestic payments without an injection of cash from creditors. At times like this, the focus is always on getting a deal done, but this negotiation, even if successful, is likely to defer hard choices for a few months in the hope that Greek domestic politics will change to allow a third bail-out program. The two sides are far apart, both in terms of the policies that need to be taken in the short term and the longer term vision for restoring growth. It is hard not to conclude this is a bridge to nowhere.  A few points. The two sides are farther apart than the headline numbers suggest. The revised Greek proposal offers a primary surplus of 0.75 percent this year, 1.75 percent in 2016 and 2.75 percent in 2017, compared to the creditor proposal of one, two and three percent, respectively. Seemingly small amounts and one could wrongly conclude the sides are close, but these numbers mask major differences in policy. With current policies, Greece will run a primary deficit this year of around 2/3 of a percent of GDP, and if the government moves ahead with proposed changes to labor and pension laws, the deficit could be substantially larger. Partly this deficit reflects the fall in activity, partly it reflects policy measures from the new government. Thus, even to hit the Greek targets require around 1½ percent of GDP in new measures this year, and substantial additional reforms in subsequent years. This is a lot to ask of a government built on a fragile coalition of interests and elected to do the opposite. Elections have consequences. The core policies in any deal are well known. Creditors have outlined a set of proposals that will need to form the basis for any deal. They reportedly include: (i) an increase in the VAT, currently one of the lowest in the EU, to raise collections by 1 percent of GDP; (ii) public sector wage cuts of 1 percent annually starting next year; (iii) pension cuts of around 1 percent of GDP by 2017 to put the pension system on a fully-paid basis; (iv) a redesigned social safety net system saving ½ percent of GDP per year; and (v) a labor consultation process that would put the brakes on the government’s efforts to roll back previous labor market reforms. There are also privatization proposals, but the program shouldn’t hinge on that element given the inherent uncertainty and lags involved. Creditors have signaled a willingness to negotiate the numbers, but it is hard to imagine a deal that doesn’t include these elements. The pension issue appears the most divisive, though creditors should be willing to accept a continuing pension deficit if the amounts are made up elsewhere. While pro-growth in the longer-term, these policies are a near-term drag on activity at a difficult time. To the frustration of Greece’s creditors, the government has failed on multiple occasions to come up with a coherent or well-developed set of proposals to achieve these savings. The revised Greek proposal reportedly focuses on the headline numbers and comprehensive debt relief, instead of the policies. I have long been supportive of substantial debt relief for Greece (and other overly indebted periphery countries), but I also believe that the creditor’s proposals are a reasonable price to ask in return. That is the grand bargain that should be the goal. But while both sides can be criticized, it is hard not to conclude that the government knows what policies are needed to clinch a deal, but that they are simply unwilling or unable at this point to agree to such policies. Perhaps there is a “Hastert rule” in play in Greece, and the government cannot politically go ahead with a program that does not command a majority of Syriza parliamentarians (opposition parties have signaled their willingness to support a deal). The bottom line here is that while the headline differences are small, the policy and political gulf is vast. The G7 closes ranks. At this weekend’s G7 meeting, there was a strong consensus that Greece needed to make tough and significant decisions to get a deal done.  The United States had in recent weeks been seen to be pressing European leaders to compromise, but President Obama’s statement showed little space between him and the other members of the G7:  "What it’s going to require is Greece being serious about making some important reforms not only to satisfy creditors, but, more importantly, to create a platform whereby the Greek economy can start growing again and prosper.  And so the Greeks are going to have to follow through and make some tough political choices that will be good for the long term." Domestic payments are still the trip wire. Even if most or all external debt payments were deferred or forgiven, Greece would still need additional resources in the near term while negotiations on a longer term program proceed. A bank run adds to the needs. The government proposes to meet the need through additional treasury bill issuance, which in the end would be financed by the ECB’s Emergency Liquidity Assistance (ELA). ELA exposure to Greece now stands at around €80 billion, and it is understandable that the ECB is wary of being the lender of first resort for an open-ended transitional period. But without this support, growing domestic arrears and missed payments will have a damaging effect on an already slowing economy and put further political pressure on the government. Banking controls inevitably would follow. In the end, non-payment to the IMF need not cause huge dislocations for the Greek economy. Not paying pensions or government wages in full would. The inflation tax is becoming more attractive. One often-cited advantage from leaving the eurozone is the growth boost that could come from the resultant depreciation, but that presumes that Greece could develop a vibrant non-tourist export sector with a more competitive exchange rate. That is hard to imagine being done easily given current policies. Perhaps a more powerful near-term argument for exit is simply that it relieves fiscal pressure by allowing the government to print money. The inflation tax that results is hugely distortive, but not necessarily more so than the current situation of widespread and growing domestic arrears. In the end, whether there is a deal or not is a political decision with substantial consequence for Greece and also for Europe. But beyond handicapping the deal, it is important to have a path for Greece that restores growth, and it’s hard to see how we are closer to that outcome now than before the most recent crisis.
  • Sub-Saharan Africa
    Europe’s Migrant Crisis
    This is a guest post by Amanda Roth, a former intern for the Council on Foreign Relations Africa Program. She is a graduate student at the Columbia School of International and Public Affairs, where she studies international security policy.  Last week, a ship carrying hundreds of migrants trying to reach Europe capsized in the Mediterranean, killing nearly 900. The tragic incident and unprecedented death toll has reignited a discussion of the growing migration crisis in the Mediterranean and Europe’s obligation to assist. Last year, Italy terminated Operation Mare Nostrum, an extensive and relatively successful search and rescue operation. The operation began in response to the 2013 Lampedusa crash, in which more than 300 migrants died. Under Mare Nostrum, Italy rescued thousands of migrants, housed and clothed them, and attempted to adjudicate asylum claims. However, with challenges of its own, Italy struggled to fund the program and to provide services for all migrants within its own borders. The Dublin Regulation, an EU law, dictates that the European country that is the first point of entry must handle the asylum application, leaving countries bordering the Mediterranean, such as Italy and Malta, overwhelmed by applications. Approximately 90 percent of refugees end up in only a few EU member states. European leaders refused to help fund Operation Mare Nostrum and to accommodate migrants. Some argued that rescue missions served as a “pull factor” and encouraged migrants to make the dangerous journey, knowing that they would be rescued. Unable to foot the costs itself, Italy ended the program. It’s difficult to know if Operation Mare Nostrum could have prevented this week’s tragedy. However, two things are clear. The first is the glaring fault in the logic that ended Operation Mare Nostrum—search and rescue operations in the Mediterranean aren’t a significant “pull factor” attracting migrants. Political violence in Mali, terrorism in West Africa, the Syrian civil war, and continued poverty and oppression mean that just as many people continue to make the journey. The second obvious conclusion is that search and rescue operations are a short-term fix, not a long-term solution. Operation Mare Nostrum helped save thousands of lives, but it could not address the root causes of migration from Africa and the Middle East to Europe. European leaders are gathering in Luxemburg this week to discuss possible solutions—including increased funding for operations such as Mare Nostrum, and targeted missions to arrest smugglers and dismantle their networks. Leaders gathered in Luxemburg this week should look at solutions that may help stem the flow of migrants in more incremental yet sustainable ways. While it is beyond Europe’s capacity to fix violence in Mali or stop the repressive regime in Eritrea, improving its own immigration system may help mitigate the flow and reduce deaths. Providing more funding for search and rescue is one critical step, but like that of the United States, Europe’s immigration system is deeply flawed. There are more creative solutions being discussed. Setting up processing centers in Africa and the Middle East, so individuals can apply for asylum before crossing the Mediterranean, may help. Family reunification processes can be simplified. The EU could revisit the Dublin Convention, which disproportionately burdens poorer Southern European nations with the responsibility of responding to waves of undocumented migrants. Immediately allowing for larger number of asylum claims is critical. These measures won’t stop the flow of migrants to Europe. But, they could keep the crisis from escalating. It is clear that leaders must look beyond short-term fixes, and address this issue in a more sustainable and comprehensive way.
  • Europe
    Greece—a Destabilizing Financial Squeeze
    Technical talks between Greece and the Troika concluded today without a deal, another setback for Greece as domestic financial stress mounts.  Robin Brooks at Goldman-Sachs makes the important point—financial conditions have tightened sharply, and will have adverse and destabilizing effects on growth regardless of whether there is a deal next week between Greece and its European creditors on a reform package.  Household deposits in Greece (red line in the left chart) and deposits in non-financial corporations (right chart) have fallen sharply, causing a destructive tightening in financial conditions at a time when banks are already in trouble and constricting credit. (Anecdotal evidence suggests this trend is continuing, with additional outflows from Greek banks in March.) At the same time, a severe squeeze on fiscal resources is forcing the government to make tough decisions about who to pay and who not to pay—which I have called “the politics of arrears”. Greece: Financial conditions Source: Goldman Sachs The experience with emerging markets highlights the high political and economic costs of a financial and fiscal squeeze.  In the run-up to Russia’s 1998 crisis, wage and interfirm arrears paralleled a weakening of budget discipline and were reflective of what the IMF came to call a “culture of non-payment” that undermined support for continued adjustment and was an impediment to recovery. In Argentina, after the introduction of banking sector controls in December 2001, financial conditions tightened sharply and arrears at the federal and local level mounted quickly. Paper IOUs issued by governments traded at deep discounts, and eventually most liabilities of the government and private sector were written down at preferred rates as part of an “asymmetric repesofication” by the government. A third example comes more recently from Venezuela, where the moral and political implications of continuing to pay external debt at a time when the government is running comprehensive domestic arrears and rationing foreign currency has generated a firestorm of debate. Weak fundamentals create the conditions for crisis, but payments problems determine the end game. Robin argues that the risk of Grexit is rising, and I agree; it will become increasingly hard for the government to sustain support for its program and for continued participation in the eurozone as tight financial conditions cause a renewed recession.  Recent polls show Greek support for euro membership, but that could change quickly if stress intensifies. So while the long-term sustainability of Greece in the eurozone depends on fundamentals (e.g., a competitive, flexible economy and competitive exchange rate), the decisions the government makes in coming days domestically on payments and banking controls may have more to do with the outcome of the crisis than negotiations with European finance ministers.
  • Europe
    Greece and the Politics of Arrears
    Greece is running out of money. Greek Prime Minister Alexis Tsipras’s meeting this week with German Chancellor Angela Merkel has taken some of the toxicity out of the conversation for now, but cannot mask Greece’s current collision course with its creditors. Committed to a platform on which it was elected but that it cannot pay for, and with additional EU/ECB financing conditioned on reform, the Greek government is likely to run out of money in April (if not before). If past emerging market crises are any guide, the decisions that it will then confront about who to pay and who not to—the politics of arrears—will present a critical challenge to the government and likely define the future path of the crisis. Most analysts continue to argue that a deal that allows Greece to muddle through and avoid an exit from the eurozone (“Grexit”) is the most likely outcome. This argument is usually based on the assessment that there is a deal to be had, that Prime Minister Tsipras is a realistic leader that can over time navigate his coalition to a course that balances democratic accountability and a return to growth with the reforms needed to continue to receive assistance, and that both sides have too much to lose from a messy exit. All this may be true, but the political timeline over which this scenario plays out is measured in months, while the economic timeline is measured in days. The Greek government is now moving to prepare a more detailed set of reforms (including fiscal reform, privatization, social security and labor measures), based on the February 20 Eurogroup agreement, in hope of securing the approval in coming days from eurozone finance ministers. Any agreement reached will require approval by the Greek and foreign parliaments. Interim meetings can at best provide momentum to negotiations that justify short-term financing—most likely in small amounts and conditional on progress—while these negotiations proceed. That means that Greece will soon, perhaps as early as next week, begin to run arrears. How did we get here? Tax revenue collapsed in the run up to the election, and has contracted further in the uncertainty that has followed. Further, in recent weeks, the parliament has approved a number of anti-poverty measures and a payment plan for tax debtors, generating domestic support but taking policy further away from the previously approved program. It is unclear whether more controversial, but necessary reforms could win approval. As a result, even the reduced government primary surplus of 1.5 percent of GDP looks out of reach on current policies. This is not to criticize the government for seeking to keep its election promises, but rather to stress the large and growing gulf between its plans and what European creditors are willing to support. Unsurprisingly, bank deposits have begun to flow out of the system in the past week (reportedly as much as 350–400 million euros on some days), exacerbating liquidity problems. By some reports, Greece needs about 2 billion euros to meet its remaining obligations for March and more for April when it faces material debt payments, including to the IMF. Reports are that it will be able to cover the March pension and wage payments from its deposits and it can tap the reserves of pension funds, state bodies and utilities, but the outlook from then onward is unclear. Greek officials are reportedly considering the use of IOUs for the payment of salaries and pensions, and less politically sensitive payments to suppliers are also likely to lag. In his letter to Chancellor Merkel last week, Prime Minister Tsipras signaled that the government might not have sufficient resources for April and would not make debt payments at the expense of social stability. What comes next? The Greek government would like to tap EU bailout funds, but acknowledges that will take time. In the interim, they are looking for the ECB to provide financing—primarily though the Bank of Greece’s emergency liquidity assistance (ELA) mechanism which now stands around 70 billion—to illiquid Greek banks, which in turn can buy government paper. There should be no mistake that to do so would be pure fiscal financing. Consequently, it is not surprising that the ECB has opposed lifting the 3.5 billion euro cap on the amount of T-bills it will accept as collateral in exchange for central bank loans. What we have seen in emerging market crises in the past is that the running of arrears puts extraordinary pressure on a government, and this new Greek government is unlikely to be an exception. The decision to pay some and not others involves allocative choices that will be new terrain for the government. Suppliers and other providers of government services are likely to see arrears, differing across different sectors depending on the power of the relevant ministries and the revealed priorities of the government. IOUs might circulate but likely would trade at a deep discount given poor liquidity conditions.  Capital controls may be needed to stem flight, putting further strain on the economy. Fissures within the governing coalition could open up. This process is unlikely to be structured and orderly. In the end, should Greece survive the politics of arrears, they will still need a competitive economy and sustainable fiscal finances, and it is hard to see how the government’s current program gets them there. Sustainability can be achieved through Grexit (and the subsequent devaluation and debt restructuring), or it can be done though a rewriting of contracts to get relative prices right and reduce liabilities (“internal devaluation”) followed by an easing of controls. Either is possible, though the experience of Iceland and Cyprus remind us of the difficulty of getting rid of capital controls once they are in place. Either can produce a sustainable post-crisis Greece. That will be a big decision down the road, but for now Greece’s future is likely to be decided by the decisions made in coming weeks on who gets paid.  
  • Europe
    The Meaning of Ukraine’s IMF Deal
    While today’s headlines focus on the truce agreement between Ukraine and Russia, a significant economic milestone was achieved yesterday with the IMF’s announcement that its staff has reached agreement with the government on a new four-year program. The Fund’s Board will likely consider the program next month. Whether or not the truce holds, the program is the core of western financial support for Ukraine. Is it enough? The program is for $17.5 billion, representing about $6 billion in new IMF financial commitments. This is somewhat misleading, because this amount is spread over four years, as compared to the two years remaining in the existing program it replaces. It appears that the amounts the IMF will disburse this year are broadly comparable to what they were before. Similarly, the statement that total support for Ukraine will total $40 billion would seem to represent mostly a repackaging of previously announced commitments (including $2 billion in U.S. loan guarantees and a roughly similar amount from the EU). If you believe that the program will need to be revised several times even in the best of scenarios, and could need a major rewrite later this year if events on the ground continue on their current path, then the truly additional resources, or “real water” of the announcement, is minimal. Most of the additional financing for the program comes from restructuring of private debt, which will take time to arrange but will be a condition for future drawings in the program (a similar approach was used in Uruguay in 2003). Pushing back maturities at roughly current interest rates (a “reprofiling” in Fund-speak) would provide substantial relief and keep creditors engaged in Ukraine until a time when sustainability is clearer, and seems to be what the markets are anticipating. Further, given the extraordinary uncertainty associated with the conflict, and the difficulty the IMF has in taking such factors into account in their debt sustainability assessments, it is folly to think we know now what the needed relief will be. But a deeper restructuring now that also includes some reduction of principal amount can’t be ruled out. After all, debt is much higher than previously admitted and in almost any reasonable scenario it is highly likely that the official sector will decide that a deep restructuring is needed eventually, so why not do it now?  On balance, and with the focus on assuring adequate financing through a quick deal with broad participation, reprofiling looks to be the sensible choice. But either way, the decision on private sector involvement (PSI) in this deal may well be precedential for the larger, ongoing debate over the architecture of international debt policy. The financing program would seem to assume that the $3 billion Russian bond that comes due in December would be restructured or otherwise pushed back, but presumably the documents will need to be silent on this issue, as Russian consent cannot be assumed at this point. With reserves down to $5.4 billion (from $16.3 billion in May), and external financing needs of $45-50 billion over the next three years, there is little scope for debt payment in the near term. Is the program “enough?” It is hard to see this program as creating the conditions for Ukraine to grow absent an end to the hostilities. Much higher levels of official bilateral aid will likely be required in the future if the West is truly committed to rebuilding Ukraine. Still, there are important positives from the agreement, both in terms of the government’s commitment to continue its reform effort and the West’s commitment to stick with Ukraine in the face of continued Russian aggression. The upfront measures in the program—including further sizable energy tariff increases, bank restructuring, governance reforms of state-owned enterprises, and legal changes to implement the anti-corruption and judicial reform agenda—are all desperately needed over the longer run even as the pace of reform needs to be slowed reflecting the current crisis. The degree of fiscal consolidation also seems realistic. One big question relates to the hole in the banking system, which appears much larger than originally estimated; the recent sharp decline in the exchange rate no doubt made that hole even larger. Overall, while I remain highly critical of the West’s stinginess in providing bilateral economic assistance as part of its overall strategy of support for Ukraine, the Fund has done what it could do, and it is an important bit of breathing space for the Ukrainian government.
  • Eurozone
    The Eurozone in Crisis
    The eurozone, once seen as a crowning achievement in the decades-long path toward European integration, continues to struggle with the effects of its sovereign debt crises and their implications for the future of the common currency.
  • Greece
    Will Greece Trigger a European Crisis?
    Greece’s new political leadership is set to challenge the German-led austerity policies in Europe, which could spur the rise of more anti-establishment movements across the continent, says political risk analyst Ian Bremmer.
  • Europe
    Greece: Let’s Make a Deal?
    Syriza’s victory in Greek elections yesterday, and the announcement this morning that they would rule in coalition with the right-wing Independent Greeks party, all but ensures a confrontation between Greece and its European creditors over austerity and debt. While Greek markets have continued their sell-off on the result, 10-year yields near 8.9 percent are still down from earlier this month and well below earlier crisis levels. In line with these numbers, most market analysts believe a deal is likely that would avoid a Greek exit from the eurozone, noting some moderation of Syriza’s rhetoric in recent days and upcoming meetings with creditors. But what would such a deal look like? Greece and its creditors are so far apart, their perceptions of their negotiating leverage so different, and time so short to reach an agreement, that the risk of failure seems higher than implied by market prices.  A few points. First, Syriza has promised a substantial fiscal expansion, a greater role for the state, and demanded relief from its unsustainably high debt (most of which is now owed to the public sector). I am quite sympathetic to the need for less fiscal austerity and debt relief for the periphery. And there are some interesting proposals for how that could work. But a fiscal expansion, even if it can boost growth for a bit, will only make consensual debt relief more difficult in the long run. All of these ideas have been firmly rejected by Germany and by other European creditor countries, and it is likely that any debt relief offered would involve a reduction in interest rates and payment deferrals, not cuts in nominal debt, and conditional on reforms that would make relief distant at best.  Further, the precedent such a deal would set makes it very difficult for creditor governments to agree, at least in the time frame required for Greece to stay current on its obligations. Second, any compromise agreement would need to allow the incoming government to issue new debt that would primarily be purchased by already-stretched Greek banks. That would require an extension and modification of Greece’s debt program, which expires at the end of February, and expanded ability for Greek banks to finance these purchases directly or indirectly through the European Central Bank (ECB). Such forbearance will be tough politically at a time when Greece, in word if not in deed, is repudiating its past commitments. Even if the ECB continues to extend credit on Greece’s intention to negotiate, the government would likely run out of money in July or August when some substantial debt payments come due. Markets would likely move the ’zero date’ forward if negotiations lag. The fiscal position apparently worsened sharply in the run-up to elections, as tax revenues plunged and spending rose, resulting in a smaller-than-expected primary surplus in 2014 and a deficit in early 2015. That is both good and bad for a deal. On the positive side, it allows for a fiscal path that tightens later this year but is still far less austere than the 5 percent of GDP primary surplus target under the current program—everybody wins. On the down side, it brings forward the date that the government runs out of cash and makes it harder for other European governments to endorse.  Further, it raises government debt levels well above the current level of 175 percent of GDP, clearly unsustainable absent substantial debt relief. Can the IMF support this path?  Navigating these issues will take a delicate balancing act, and a lot of near-term financing. Finally, short of a eurozone exit, but absent an extension of its IMF-backed program, Greece could finance itself through arrears and, eventually, capital controls to prevent capital from fleeing. Payments, including debt payments, would be delayed. This may well be the most likely scenario in the near term. Many point to the example of Cyprus, and note that, while still in the eurozone, there would be a de facto separation—a euro in Athens would not be the same as a euro in Berlin. However, the Cyprus program was based on the (controversial) assumption that it could adjust and exit the controls with a competitive economy, a story far harder to tell in Greece. Even in the best of circumstances, controls are hard to remove. Unless you believe that, with time, a fiscal-driven boost to growth is all Greece needs to achieve longer-run competitiveness and sustainability, there would not be a path to normalization that did not involve a significant markdown of Greek debt. If that “unilateral” debt restructuring was unacceptable to the rest of Europe, it is easy to imagine that exit, even if delayed, would be the end result of the process. My bottom line is that the new government can produce a temporary growth surge inside or outside the eurozone, but that the main scenarios for doing so make consensual debt relief harder, not easier to achieve. Whatever the longer-run consequences of the new government’s plans, an eventual exit from the eurozone seems more likely than not. While Europe is better prepared than 2010–12 for such an event, the substantial losses that would result with either exit or capital controls would have broad repercussions. Moreover, any growth in Greece will embolden anti-austerity parties elsewhere in Europe. In a year, the debate may be over whether the rest of the periphery should copy Greece, not the other way around.
  • Europe
    What a Syriza Victory Would Mean for Europe
    This weekend’s snap election in Greece could determine the direction of the country’s future, as well as shift the economic course for the rest of the eurozone, says expert Eleni Panagiotarea.
  • Sub-Saharan Africa
    An African Odyssey
    This is a guest post by Amanda Roth, a former intern for the Council on Foreign Relations Africa Program. She is a graduate student at the Columbia School of International and Public Affairs, where she studies international security policy Last year, the horrific shipwreck off the Italian island of Lampedusa brought international attention to the dangers faced by the thousands of migrants who cross the Mediterranean Sea to find safety in Europe. The wreck, which occurred less than a quarter-mile from Italy’s shores, killed 366 migrants from Eritrea and Somalia. The Mediterranean is the world’s deadliest migrant crossing, according to the International Organization for Migration, with more than three thousand reported deaths so far this year. That number is up from approximately seven hundred the year before, and accounts for 75 percent of all documented migrant deaths worldwide. More people are making the journey from Africa and more people are dying. In response, the Italian government launched Operation Mare Nostrum. Run by the Italian Coast Guard, the operation has saved the lives of more than 150,000 people. Yet, as of November 1, 2014, Operation Mare Nostrum came to an end, leaving the fate of the thousands of migrants expected to attempt future journeys uncertain. There is no adequate replacement for the now-expired Operation Mare Nostrum. Despite the program’s success, it ended due to “unsustainable” costs. Instead, Mare Nostrum will be replaced by Operation Triton, which is run by the EU and is significantly smaller in scope and has one-third the budget of Mare Nostrum. It will not have an explicit search and rescue function. Instead, the operation will only patrol within thirty miles of Italy’s borders. There is little political support among EU governments for larger search and rescue missions. Last week, the United Kingdom announced that it would not contribute to future rescue missions. Although the country has received harsh criticism for the decision, James Brokenshire, UK immigration minister, defended the choice, arguing that “since Italy launched its Mare Nostrum operation in October 2013, there has been an unprecedented increase in illegal immigration across the Mediterranean and a four-fold increase in the deaths of those making that perilous journey.” Networks of smugglers charge migrants large sums of money in exchange for passage. These human traffickers have been accused of grave human rights abuses, including the rape and torture of migrants. The UK and others accuse the smugglers of abusing existing search and rescue missions by knowingly using unsafe boats and hoping their human cargo is rescued and brought to European shores. Does Operation Mare Nostrum encourage migrants to make the dangerous journey? Although it may contribute, it isn’t the entire reason. Ongoing conflicts and brutal repression in Somalia, Eritrea, and elsewhere have caused tens of thousands of refugees to flee. Turmoil in northern Africa following the Arab Spring means that fewer refugees are settling in Egypt and Libya, preferring to risk the crossing to the EU. While Italy’s Mare Nostrum has saved tens of thousands of lives, it still hasn’t been able to respond to the full scope of the crisis. A few days after the UK’s announcement in October, for example, a boat sank off the coast of Libya. Although the Italian Coast Guard rescued ninety-three people, another twenty African migrants died. Tightened border security, stricter scrutiny of asylum claims, and the close patrol of traditional land routes have driven many migrants to try and reach Europe by sea. Now that Mare Nostrum has ended, many more are likely to die. Despite the United Kingdom’s claims, it’s far from clear that the decision not to support rescue missions will reduce the numbers of people making the journey. Will the European Union really turn its back on the thousands of refugees trying to reach safe shores?
  • Europe
    G20 Worries About Growth
    The central message from the G20 Summit in Brisbane last weekend was the need for more growth, and there was a clear sense after the meeting that leaders are worried. David Cameron captured the mood with his statement that “red warning lights are flashing on the dashboard of the global economy” and his concern about “a dangerous backdrop of instability and uncertainty.” While Europe came in for the most criticism (Christine Lagarde rightly worries that high debt, low growth and unemployment may yet become “the new normal in Europe”) concerns about growth in Japan and emerging markets also weighed on leaders. In the end, though, the diplomacy conducted on the sidelines was more meaningful than the growth proposals put forward at the summit. Leaders put forward over 800 policy commitments that they assert will raise global growth by over 2 percent by 2018, but on first look there is little additional here that will actually be implemented. For the United States, for example, the commitments reflect the Administration’s fiscal agenda, including stimulus proposals with no real chance of congressional approval. In Europe, the commitments also reflect fiscal and structural measures that seem highly optimistic and at odds with the current policy paralysis there. Leaders also made sweeping commitments in the areas of trade and infrastructure, with a commitment to information sharing on best practices in infrastructure that makes a lot of sense but is unlikely to move the needle on global growth. Nonetheless, the IMF gave cover to leaders, stating the measures would meet the growth target “if implemented fully,” an assessment that was polite but not a service to the debate. Perhaps the peer pressure embedded in the process (leaders committed to review these policies next year), will produce better policies in the future, but the effort looks a lot like the IMF’s failed mutual assessment process (MAP) and I am not optimistic that it will work better at the leaders’ level. These summits also give a push to ongoing reform efforts, and the Brisbane iteration was no exception. There was endorsement of an anti-corruption action plan, focusing on improving transparency in financial flows (including importantly going after shell companies offshore). Leaders also called on countries to ensure that information is shared between domestic and international agencies, including law-enforcement bodies. Work on international tax avoidance was endorsed. Measures to end too-big-to-fail were advanced. These are good and important steps, and represent a lot of serious expert work leading up to the summit. The challenge now is to match words with deeds. From a U.S. perspective, the most important achievements came outside of the G20 meetings: an agreement with India to advance the WTO trade facilitation package agreed in Bali last year, apparent progress on the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP), and accords between China and the United States on limits of CO2 emissions and on IT trade. The energy shown on the trade agenda is heartening, but at the same time I worry that any agreement will be a tougher sell with the Congress than many expect. The administration’s request for trade promotion authority will be an early test. Overall, the G20 Summit and surrounding meetings did as much as could be expected, and perhaps a little more. At times of crisis, the G-20 is extremely effective at finding common cause and working together on crisis solutions. In calmer times, such as the present, agreement is harder to achieve. Despite this trend, let’s hope that the next G20 summit isn’t a crisis meeting.
  • Europe
    Three Central Banks
    Today’s central bank news tells us a lot about the risks and rewards of proactive central banking. The Bank of Japan (BoJ) surprised me (and nearly everyone else ) with a dramatic expansion of its unconventional monetary policy this morning, citing renewed risks of deflation. The BOJ announced (i) an increase in the target for monetary base growth to ¥80 trillion ($730 billion) per annum from ¥60–70 trillion; (2) an increase in its Japanese government bond (JGB) purchases to an annual pace of ¥80 trillion from ¥50 trillion; (3) an extension of the average maturity of its JGB purchases to 7–10 years (3 years previously); and (4) a tripling of its targets for the annual purchases of Japan real estate investment trusts (J-REITs) and exchange-traded funds (ETFs). In addition, and more controversially, the Japanese Government Pension Investment Fund (GPIF) will shift its portfolio away from government bonds and towards equities, both domestic and foreign, doubling the share of equities to 50 percent. As a general rule it’s not such a good idea to use government wealth funds as an instrument of monetary policy in this way, but given that government policy in the past has been so heavily tilted towards support of the bond market, it can be argued that this is a good move from a longer-run perspective, and it does arguably strengthen the near-term wealth effects of quantitative easing. It is also worth noting that the BoJ has followed the lead of other central banks and moved away from date-based guidance (achieving 2 percent inflation within two years of the start of the program, a target that was always optimistic and now quickly slipping out of reach) to a focus on balance sheet targets. That makes sense. There was a fair degree of attention paid to the fact that the vote was 5-4 for easing. For most central banks, such a closely divided vote would be a negative. Here, however, I see decisiveness. As long as we assume BoJ Governor Haruhiko Kuroda can command a majority on critical decisions, which I do, his willingness to move proactively as soon as a majority exists shows strength. There is some speculation in the markets that the BoJ move was given a green light when the U.S. Treasury did not mention yen weakness as a concern in its recent exchange rate report. I think this is oversold as an explanation. What I do see at play is a central bank that--while motivated by domestic considerations--is taking advantage of the Fed’s turn toward normalization to make a dramatic move that, by emphasizing the divergence of policy, ensures a substantial market impact. Today the yen reached a six-year low against the dollar at 112.4 and stocks rose sharply. That said, I would not be surprised to see exchange rate tensions intensify in coming months and feature centrally in upcoming G-7 and G-20 debates. The BoJ’s move could put additional pressure of the European Central Bank (ECB) to act when it meets next week, though few analysts expect a move to purchase government bonds (sovereign QE) until December at the earliest and more likely next year. There may well be a narrow majority for such a move, but in contrast to the BOJ, failure to act (combined with muddy messaging) ensures that monetary policy will continue to provide weak support for the recovery. Europe needs its own “three arrows”, as well as more aggressive action to deal with the crushing debt overhang. Finally, the Central Bank of Russia surprised markets with a 150 bp increase in interest rates, raising the benchmark rate to 9.5 percent from 5.5 percent at the start of the tightening cycle. With inflation at 8.4 percent and rising (against a target of 5.5 percent), and food inflation several points higher, the central bank was pressured to act. However, the currency sold off following the announcement, despite announcement of an oil agreement with Ukraine, reading the move as a sign of a sharply weakening economy and recognition of the limited commitment of the central bank to defend the currency. I think that is right. The economy is headed for a deep recession, capital flight is continuing, and sanctions are more likely to be intensified than eased in coming months.  In sum, it’s hard not to expect that capital controls will soon follow.