Economics

Economic Crises

  • Russia
    How Disruptive Is Russia’s Ruble Dive?
    Russia’s options for combatting the plunge of the ruble are dwindling, but government intervention is likely to intensify in efforts to avert a full-blown crisis, says CFR’s Robert Kahn.
  • Europe
    G20 Worries About Growth
    The central message from the G20 Summit in Brisbane last weekend was the need for more growth, and there was a clear sense after the meeting that leaders are worried. David Cameron captured the mood with his statement that “red warning lights are flashing on the dashboard of the global economy” and his concern about “a dangerous backdrop of instability and uncertainty.” While Europe came in for the most criticism (Christine Lagarde rightly worries that high debt, low growth and unemployment may yet become “the new normal in Europe”) concerns about growth in Japan and emerging markets also weighed on leaders. In the end, though, the diplomacy conducted on the sidelines was more meaningful than the growth proposals put forward at the summit. Leaders put forward over 800 policy commitments that they assert will raise global growth by over 2 percent by 2018, but on first look there is little additional here that will actually be implemented. For the United States, for example, the commitments reflect the Administration’s fiscal agenda, including stimulus proposals with no real chance of congressional approval. In Europe, the commitments also reflect fiscal and structural measures that seem highly optimistic and at odds with the current policy paralysis there. Leaders also made sweeping commitments in the areas of trade and infrastructure, with a commitment to information sharing on best practices in infrastructure that makes a lot of sense but is unlikely to move the needle on global growth. Nonetheless, the IMF gave cover to leaders, stating the measures would meet the growth target “if implemented fully,” an assessment that was polite but not a service to the debate. Perhaps the peer pressure embedded in the process (leaders committed to review these policies next year), will produce better policies in the future, but the effort looks a lot like the IMF’s failed mutual assessment process (MAP) and I am not optimistic that it will work better at the leaders’ level. These summits also give a push to ongoing reform efforts, and the Brisbane iteration was no exception. There was endorsement of an anti-corruption action plan, focusing on improving transparency in financial flows (including importantly going after shell companies offshore). Leaders also called on countries to ensure that information is shared between domestic and international agencies, including law-enforcement bodies. Work on international tax avoidance was endorsed. Measures to end too-big-to-fail were advanced. These are good and important steps, and represent a lot of serious expert work leading up to the summit. The challenge now is to match words with deeds. From a U.S. perspective, the most important achievements came outside of the G20 meetings: an agreement with India to advance the WTO trade facilitation package agreed in Bali last year, apparent progress on the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP), and accords between China and the United States on limits of CO2 emissions and on IT trade. The energy shown on the trade agenda is heartening, but at the same time I worry that any agreement will be a tougher sell with the Congress than many expect. The administration’s request for trade promotion authority will be an early test. Overall, the G20 Summit and surrounding meetings did as much as could be expected, and perhaps a little more. At times of crisis, the G-20 is extremely effective at finding common cause and working together on crisis solutions. In calmer times, such as the present, agreement is harder to achieve. Despite this trend, let’s hope that the next G20 summit isn’t a crisis meeting.
  • Budget, Debt, and Deficits
    The International Economic Agenda Facing the New Congress
    The initial post-election talk is understandably about whether the shift to a Republican controlled Senate makes it easier or harder to make progress on central economic challenges facing the United States, including energy, immigration, social spending, and infrastructure. There is understandable concern that this next Congress will face the same gridlock that we have now. But even before that, there is the mundane issue of what we borrow and spend. Partly out of fear of being seen as crying wolf one too many times, I have been wary to advertise my concern that we are facing a new series of economic cliffs. First up is a likely standoff on the budget (in December, and likely again in the spring of 2015). Then comes the debt limit, which will be reset on March 15, but given the usual and not-terribly-extraordinary “extraordinary measures” that are at the disposal of Treasury, they can likely pay the nation’s bills until perhaps the fall of 2015 before cash balances fall to zero. Of course, in the past deals have been done, often at the last minute, and we have not, with the exception of the 2013 government shutdown, gone off the cliff (though there have been a few unnecessary fender benders along the way). But with the Senate as polarized as ever, it is easy to see getting to deals on these issues will be difficult and potentially unsettling to markets. I am concerned that one cost of this focus on fiscal cliffs will be failure to deal with the long list of international economic issues that are in front of the Congress. Notably, there is a great deal of optimism that the Senate will now provide the President with trade promotion authority (TPA), which likely is essential to have any chance of meaningful agreements on the trade negotiations now underway, including the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) and the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP). This optimism seems to come from the historical Republican support for free trade, and recognition that it was Senate Democrats that were the primary hurdle to its passage till now. Perhaps such optimism is justified, and there is previously proposed legislation that should be able to garner bipartisan support. But do not underestimate the risk that negotiations could go off track. In the past, there has been pressure from both parties for tough language requiring any trade deal to address exchange rate misalignments, and that pressure is likely to mount if dollar strength becomes seen as a risk for the economy. Such exchange rate language could be a killer here. The debate over border policies and distrust between the parties also may complicate these negotiations. This is far from a done deal. The administration should also take the opportunity to reintroduce the proposed IMF reform package, which would slightly increase the resources available to the IMF and, far more importantly, increase the voice given to rising emerging market powers at the institution. Failure to do so will have substantial geopolitical consequences if it pushes those countries to attempt to operate outside of global institutions such as the IMF and World Bank. We are already seeing the effects of Congressional inaction on this issue with the Chinese launch of an Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank. The IMF also has signaled that it will develop new plans for addressing the demands of rising powers for a bigger say if we do not act by end year. (For example, there are proposals to proceed with a reform without full U.S. participation, but that would likely eliminate the U.S. veto over changes in the Fund’s articles, a major concession.) The end result if we don’t act will be a dilution of U.S. economic leadership and influence on global economic governance issues, something even Congressional critics of the IMF presumably do not want to see. A battle also is shaping up on the reauthorization of the Export-Import Bank, with temporary reauthorization set to expire in June 2015. I would not be surprised to see action blocked by a small, but passionate opposition to any governmental role in trade finance. There further will be a lot of debate over international financial regulatory agenda, as part of a debate over Dodd-Frank legislation, but whether that leads to legislation is uncertain.  There does seem to be bipartisan support to take a new look at the impact of the global post-crisis reform effort on areas of strength and comparative advantage for the U.S. financial system, including insurance and asset management rules.  Finally, I expect to see new sanctions legislation proposed relating to both Iran and Russia. On Russia, I have been opposed to legislation, concerned that it would make sanctions too sticky and hard to remove should there be a future agreement easing the crisis.  But many in Congress want an even tougher approach than we have seen from the Obama Administration. Altogether, a long to do list, and not a great deal of reason for optimism that there will be substantial progress achieved. I hope I am wrong.
  • United States
    Alan Greenspan on Central Banks, Stagnation, and Gold
    Play
    Alan Greenspan, former chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, joins Gillian Tett, U.S. managing editor at the Financial Times, to discuss current trends in the global economy and solutions for addressing the financial crisis.
  • United States
    Alan Greenspan on Central Banks, Stagnation, and Gold
    Play
    Alan Greenspan, former chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, joins Gillian Tett, U.S. managing editor at the Financial Times, to discuss current trends in the global economy and solutions for addressing the financial crisis.
  • Europe
    A Paris Club for Europe
    Europe's strategy for solving its debt woes has the problem exactly backwards. A gaping hole in Europe's policy response to date is its unwillingness to reduce excessive levels of corporate, bank, and sovereign debt accrued during the global financial crisis and its aftermath. This debt has had a corrosive effect on investment and confidence, contributes to deflationary pressures, and undermines the public's trust in its economic future. Yet European leaders have not definitively addressed this challenge, hopeful that payment deferrals and an eventual return to growth will allow countries to outgrow their debt. This policy has produced a temporary improvement in market access at the cost of longer-term sustainability, contributing to an anemic recovery that is insufficient to address extremely high unemployment rates. A lost decade looms. A comprehensive, predictable, and rules-based program of debt reduction for over-indebted countries in the periphery of Europe can break the cycle of low growth and rising debt. Though there are many ways forward, one promising approach comes from the Paris Club, the informal group of official creditors that provides debt relief to low-income countries conditional on strong economic performance. The Problem: Growth, Debt, and the Doom Loop In the four years since Greece first approached the International Monetary Fund (IMF) for a bailout, the periphery countries have been at the epicenter of the crisis. In response, Europe created rescue funds, eased monetary policy, and made substantial structural reforms to labor and product markets. As a consequence, Europe has moved beyond the series of crises and emergency weekend meetings that dominated the last several years. Backed by strong policy support from the European Central Bank (ECB), capital has flowed back into the debt of periphery countries. However, it would be a mistake to assume that the crisis is resolved. The outlook for growth—at around 1 percent through 2015—remains below trend and far too low to meaningfully reduce crushingly high levels of unemployment, especially youth unemployment, which exceeds 35 percent in Spain, Greece, Portugal, and Italy. As the sense of crisis has receded, the pressure for ambitious solutions has dissipated. Yet opinion polls show a growing dissatisfaction with Europe's course, and May's European parliamentary elections delivered a strong message of voter impatience with current leaders and their policies. The pressing challenge for Europe is to restore growth before markets and voters again lose confidence in the reform process. One of the central lessons from past crises is that high levels of debt can be a substantial and sustained drag on growth. In recent years, European governments have seen explosive increases in their debt ratios. In some cases, this reflects large fiscal deficits (e.g., Greece and Portugal); in other cases, the costs of supporting national banks played a significant role (e.g., Ireland and Spain). Low growth contributes to balance-sheet stress for banks and corporations, which in turn exacerbates financial distress—a "doom loop" between sovereigns and their banks that will damage growth. In the near term, ECB support ensures that these countries retain market access, but at the cost of higher future debt. Over time, rising debt service costs will exact a price in terms of confidence, reduced cross-border investment, and fragmented credit markets that will be particularly damaging for smaller, non-systemic borrowers across the periphery of Europe.. The sharing of costs across the union would break the doom loop. Yet a defining feature of the European policy response to the crisis has been concern over moral hazard and resistance to the notion that Europe would become a "transfer union." Creditor countries—led by Germany—consequently have insisted that the mechanisms through which fiscal union would be achieved—e.g., eurobonds and fiscal transfer, or a full banking union that shares costs of bank restructuring—can only come at the end of the reform process, if at all. Rather than acknowledge that the legacy debt has to be reduced to make current policies sustainable and create incentives for new investment, countries are forced to shoulder the burden of that debt with the uncertain hope of future debt relief. This presents two problems. First, it is highly uncertain that debt relief offered through undefined future interest-rate reductions will be adequate to restore debt sustainability. Second, the overhang of debt in effect subordinates other investors—including private investors—to official creditors. There is no single percentage of debt relative to gross domestic product (GDP) above which a country is definitively insolvent. That threshold will vary across countries based on a range of economic, political, and social factors. But resolving the debt overhang in the periphery will require acknowledging that it will be nearly impossible for these countries to grow their way out of existing debt levels. There would appear to be increasing acceptance of the need for debt relief, but an inability, at least for now, to discuss it. Greece in the Vanguard (Again) Nowhere is the corrosive linkage between debt and growth more on display than in Greece. Two years after its debt restructuring, the government had a successful return to markets, issuing a five-year bond at 4.95 percent. Investors' interest was supported by a reach for yield and a view that a short-term bond issue will be paid before the current moratorium on interest payments expires in eight years, rather than an improved sense of Greece's long-term creditworthiness. Such optimism may be short-lived, and policymakers may soon need to acknowledge that substantial further debt relief is needed. Greek public debt even after restructuring is around 175 percent of GDP, and in the IMF's low-growth scenario sees little or no improvement over the next decade. Greece is not alone. Throughout Europe, corporate debt is high and rising, while the European Central Bank­–led banking assessment at the end of October will lead to additional costs of cleaning up the banking system. Ultimately, the responsibility for fixing corporate and bank balance sheets will fall on national governments. A contentious public debate may refocus investor attention on the unsustainability of current debt levels. Paris Club Lessons It is an unfortunate reality that over the last thirty years the world has had a great deal of practice resolving international debt crises. Though the circumstances differ, one common theme runs through the official responses to the developing-country debt crisis of the 1980s, the East Asian financial crisis of the 1990s, and the Great Recession. In addition to the implementation of new policies to reduce the risk of future crises, each case required a solution to the debt overhang in order to achieve a durable return to growth. Fortunately, there is an effective model for dealing with a debt overhang: the Paris Club, an informal group of official creditors that has met since 1956 to deal with payment problems of emerging market debtor countries. For countries in crisis, the Paris Club provides rescheduling of sovereign debt owed to official creditors. Though the Paris Club's operations, geared as they are to low- and middle-income countries under IMF programs, may seem ill-designed for the large, complex industrial economies of Europe, three of its principles should be central to the European approach. First, the Paris Club has a set of rules for the terms of restructuring based on the countries' income and debt level and are known in advance. In practice, the scale of debt relief will depend on a case-by-case assessment of the financing need of each program. Second, Paris Club restructurings are conditional on a proven record of performance under an IMF program. In the European context, there is an unfortunate stigma associated with IMF programs and conditionality, but nonetheless making relief conditional on performance is essential to address legitimate moral hazard concerns. The third principle is seniority for new lending and for trade finance. The Paris Club sets a cutoff date and the restructuring, as well as any future restructuring, will apply only to debt originally contracted before that date. New lending is therefore senior to old debt, in practice, which creates an environment that encourages capital to return. If this framework extended to Europe's periphery, confidence and incentives for new lending would be strengthened. What Europe Should Do Next With the release of the banking assessment and stress test toward the end of October, uncertainty about the effects of debt relief on banks is no longer an excuse for inaction. Europe needs to begin negotiations this year on a rules-based approach to official-sector debt relief, in which countries meeting firm conditionality would be assured of adequate (and predictable) relief. This approach would have the following elements: countries would receive a cutoff date and debt acquired before that date would be eligible for restructuring; restructurings would be tranched; and assistance would be conditional on policy performance, including structural reforms, continued progress toward macroeconomic balance, and programs for restructuring over-indebted corporate sectors. Though it is difficult to quantify the effect of reducing debt on the European economy, some estimates suggest that the resultant rebound in investment could raise European trend growth by up to one percentage point. Critics will argue that debt relief is unnecessary when maturities have been extended and where additional concessions could be offered in the future if needed. That argument fails to be convincing, as the current approach creates uncertainty about whether adequate relief will be given, which policies the country should implement, and if austerity will someday end. Further, as seen in the case of Greece, long-term official debt does not impose market discipline on private lenders (though it does mean that new private debt will be short term, exacerbating the risk of future runs). European leaders are understandably concerned about the costs of setting precedents when dealing with the crisis of the moment, as well as implementing a crisis-management approach associated with low-income emerging markets. But the costs of inaction are growing too large. Europe needs a Paris Club for European debt. Call it a consultative group if need be; hold it in Berlin, Amsterdam, or Brussels. The sooner these rules are established, the sooner Europe will see a return to growth.
  • Europe
    When meetings matter—The World Bank and IMF Convene
    There are many reasons cited for this week’s market turndown and risk pullback, including concerns about global growth, Ebola, turmoil in the Middle East, and excessive investor comfort from easy money. What has been less commented on is the role played by last weekend’s IMF and World Bank Annual Meetings. Sometimes these meetings pass uneventfully, but sometimes bringing so many people together—policymakers and market people—creates a conversation that moves the consensus and as a result moves markets. It seems this year’s was one of those occasions. As the meetings progressed, optimism about a G-20 growth agenda and infrastructure boom receded and concerns about growth outside of the United States began to dominate the discussion. The perception that policymakers—particularly European policymakers—were either unable or unwilling to act contributed to the gloom. Time will tell whether macro risk factors that markets have shrugged off over the past few years will now be a source of volatility going forward. But if that is the case, perhaps these meetings had something to do with it. A few other thoughts on the meetings. Markets are ahead of policymakers on European QE. Europe is divided on whether quantitative easing is needed, and if tried, whether it will be effective. While most market participants seem to expect the ECB to soon extend its program of quantitative easing to buying government bonds, current and ex-central bankers at presentations I attended signaled a greater degree of uncertainty. Part of the concern is whether the usual channels through which QE works—including a wealth effect on portfolios—will work as well in Europe’s bank dominated system as it did in the United States, but the greater concern is gridlocked politics. This was highlighted by the public disagreement between ECB head Draghi and Bundesbank President Weidmann, as noted by several commentators. The risk is that the easing of policy comes late, and doesn’t pack the punch that is needed to restore growth. We know from the U.S. experience that a potentially important channel for unconventional monetary policy comes from the forward guidance it provides that easy policy will be sustained. True, the ECB has some tools the Fed does not have (e.g., long-term fixed rate lending facilities) to signal that rates will stay low for a long time. Yet, at a time when policymakers elsewhere are increasingly focused on the challenge of exiting that guidance, the hesitancy of the ECB to clearly articulate its goals for and commitment to an expansion of its balance sheet and increased liquidity can only undermine the impact of current monetary policy. The policy response to divergent monetary policies is starting to take shape. Much of the policy discussion tried to anticipate a world in which the Federal Reserve began to normalize policy while the Bank of Japan and ECB expanded their use of unconventional monetary policies. Exchange rates, particularly emerging market exchange rates, were seen as a source of future volatility. In this regard, I was surprised I did not hear more about the risk of protectionism (in the United States for example if the dollar rises sharply) or capital controls (in emerging markets) if we have a normalization nightmare, following on the taper tantrum of last year. The continued criticism of the Fed by Indian central bank governor Rajan seems to have less to do with policy (the Fed’s actions having supported global growth and its possible exit well communicated) as much as it may suggest preparation to resist the market pressures that will result. The outlook is deteriorating for Russia and Ukraine. There is increasing anecdotal evidence that pressures on the Russian financial system are mounting and extending to non-sanctioned banks. The recent depreciation of the rouble and capital outflows have intensified concerns, and notwithstanding substantial central bank and government support it seems clear that Russia has dropped into recession. Most of the market forecasts still see positive growth this year, but I expect that to change after these meetings. Meanwhile, I didn’t need the meetings to tell me that the IMF’s program for Ukraine is collapsing, a victim of continued Russian destabilization, a deep recession, and ridiculously optimistic initial IMF assumptions. What surprised me was the weak defense put up by the official community at these meetings. The IMF team that will go to Kiev in early November, after Parliamentary elections, has little choice but to positively conclude its review and disburse the roughly $2.7 billion due Ukraine in December, given rising cash needs of the government heading into winter. But I suspect (and hope) that the review will acknowledge the large and growing financing needs of the country and the limits of the Fund’s ability to meet these needs and introduce sustainable economic reform in the midst of a conflict. The Fund should signal that it may have to step back as soon as the next review (in March), and that bilateral support from the United States and European governments needs to fill the gap. That new package (with a private debt restructuring to extend maturities) needs to be in place by March, if not sooner.
  • Budget, Debt, and Deficits
    IMF/World Bank Meetings: In Search of a Consensus
    This week’s Annual Meetings of the World Bank and IMF will have a lot of discussion but little action.  Here are five things that I anticipate will capture some headlines. Growth is important...but what are you going to do about it?  I suspect that we will hear broad frustration from policymakers about the tepid global recovery.  Most expect a gradual global recovery to below average levels, as the scars from the financial crisis and weak policies constrain growth.  But there isn’t much on the table in terms of macro policies that can be debated and changed, and while there is a lot of structural work to be done (e.g., financial sector and labor market reform) we are unlikely to see much real progress on a growth agenda this week. Infrastructure is (a public) good.  Everyone can agree that there is a critical need for additional infrastructure, but unclear what to do about it.  Private sector projects should be encouraged, but appear limited by legal and commercial considerations, and while there is a clear case for public provision of infrastructure ("public goods"), budgets are constrained and standards (including importantly environmental standards) limit governments’ capacity to respond.  The Fund calls for more efficiency and a push by countries that have the budget space.  Beyond that, the Chinese-led initiative for an Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB), and to a lesser extent the slower-moving BRICs Bank, will be a focus.  There appears to be a great deal of energy behind the AIIB, but it’s hard to imagine it scaling up quickly without risking a major weakening of standards, poor project selection or “capture” by borrowing countries.  Can the AIIB collaborate effectively with the World Bank and Asian Development Bank and avoid fragmentation? Is geopolitical risk a major threat to markets? As I have written, policymakers are concerned by the apparent disconnect between rising geopolitical risk and a benign market outlook.  The concern is legitimate, but there is little consensus that economic policymakers should say or do anything differently.  Still, this discussion will be an important part of the hallway debate.  There are broader questions here about the global economic architecture.  Are we headed towards comprehensive financial sanctions against Russia, and if so, would restrictions on the payments system threaten a basic “public good?” Where is the IMF going on debt policy?  The Fund recently endorsed the introduction of new clauses in debt contracts, addressing the inter-creditor equity problems highlighted by Argentina’s legal battle with its creditors and strengthening the ability of distressed debtors to coordinate with their creditors on a solution.  This is all to the good, though it arguably would have happened even without the Fund’s involvement.  The real challenge— how do we encourage the quick transformation of the existing stock of debt (which doesn’t have the clauses) into new debt—is still to be addressed.  Look for some discussion this week of ways in which the official community can provide a push to efforts to swap old debt for new debt (through market exchanges) with the improved clause. More broadly, the IMF continues to develop the case for new rules governing its lending, including a greater focus on extending the maturity of private debt when it is lending large amounts in risky situations.  I am not convinced that there is a problem in debt markets that needs solving, or that this is the solution.  The debate this week may instead focus on the so-called “systemic exemption,” which gives the major countries the ability to bend Fund rules for lending when systemic issues are in play (e.g., Greece, Ireland).   The IMF would like to constrain or eliminate that rule, and while I’m sympathetic, it is not realistic in my view to expect the major countries to tie their hands regarding how they respond to global crisis. IMF reform (still) stalled.  There is growing international frustration with the failure of the United States to pass the IMF quota and governance reform package.  My read of the environment in the U.S. Congress is that the chances of passage this year are lower than ever before, so the international community will need to begin to talk publicly about what comes next.
  • International Organizations
    Financing Ukraine: Time for an Honest Assessment
    Russia’s invasion of Ukraine (“incursion” is far too polite a term) represents a major intensification of the conflict and should cross all red lines the West has established.  The logic of the earlier, incremental approach—put modest sanctions in place, and let the threat of worse create a chilling effect on investment and trade—has reached a dead end.  Whether President Putin seeks a stalemate within Ukraine or something more menacing, full sectoral sanctions (including, importantly, Russia’s access to payments systems) should now be put in place as a firm signal of western resolve.  The real cost-benefit to be done is not the costs on the West compared to Russia. Rather it is those relative costs contrasted against doing nothing and risking a situation that brings us closer to either armed conflict or acceptance of a new rule that states can redraw boundaries by force. German President Merkel has signaled that further sanctions are on the agenda for the September 30 EU leaders summit, and I expect the Obama Administration will move with them if not before. While military developments will dominate the headlines in coming days, Ukraine’s economic collapse should not be forgotten.  Another necessary piece of the West’s response is enhanced economic assistance. The IMF meets tomorrow to conclude their first review of their program for Ukraine.  They will, no doubt, forgive the slippages and missed commitments and conclude the review, which will clear the way for disbursal of at least $1.4 billion.  The Fund has also signaled today their willingness to move money forward from the back part of the program –“recalibrating” the program—in order to meet a widening financing gap.   This could include boosting the next disbursement, or combining the next two reviews, in order to get more money out the door to Ukraine in coming months. The bottom line is that the Fund must acknowledge a major revision to its outlook for Ukraine.  That makes sense, as the original program assumptions (see below) were wildly unrealistic at the time and are a dead letter now.  The deterioration of economic conditions since that time is significantly due to Russian aggression, but not entirely. The legacy of past economic mistakes and even modest austerity is contributing to a deep economic recession. I suspect that the worsening on the situation on the ground likely makes even these new assumptions a receding hope. A  realistic forecast would show a widening fiscal hole and unsustainable debt dynamics, even assuming Ukraine remains whole and free. That means that the real message from tomorrow’s IMF Board meeting will be that the program is badly underfinanced, and will need a substantial rethink in coming months.  That means either substantially more bilateral assistance from Europe or debt restructuring.  Markets still do not price this outcome.  Many market analysts note that there is only one sovereign-backed Eurobond maturing this year, a $1.6 billion Naftogaz bond due at end September, and that the IMF program already in principle provides the financing to pay this bond.  Why then make waves ahead of parliamentary elections scheduled for October 26 and given the uncertainty of Russia’s actions?  I have sympathy for this argument, but at the same time, the Fund’s internal rules require it to assert that the program is adequately financed, which means looking forward two years.  Further, there may well be strong political as well as economic benefits for the Ukrainian government of a more full-throated effort to bail in its creditors.  Honesty (and credibility) requires the kind of warnings that will make headlines in coming days.  It is hard to imagine that we do not begin to have the debate. Original IMF  Program (5/14) Current Market Estimates GDP Growth in 2014 -5.0% -8.0% to -10.0% Public Debt/GDP in 2018 61% 70%–80% Exchange Rate (per USD) in 2014 10.5 13.9 (current rate; 16 in black market) Fiscal deficit/GDP in 2014 -8.5% -10% to -11%
  • Budget, Debt, and Deficits
    BRICS and Mortals
    Leaders of the BRICS--Brazil, Russia, India, China, and South Africa--meet in Rio today to swap World Cup stories and launch a long-discussed "BRICS Bank." The bank creates two funds--a development lending facility (New Development Bank or NDB) backed by $50 billion in capital ($10 billion from each of the BRICs), and a $100 billion rescue fund (Contingent Reserve Arrangement, CRA) for countries suffering from exogenous shocks. There is a great deal of optimism surrounding the launch of the institution, with some seeing it as a serious political and economic counterweight over time to the World Bank and IMF. While the political motivations for the initiative are easy to identify, the economic benefits are much harder to pin down. I am skeptical that the BRICS Bank will be an effective development institution or rescue facility, and see serious risks that its good ambitions could be undermined by poor investments, bad policies, and even corruption. Here are five reasons why. 1. No obvious pot of high-quality investments. Part of the motivation for a new development bank is to meet an unfilled need for development projects the World Bank and regional development banks cannot or will not fund. The early focus of the NDB is on infrastructure, and I would fully agree that there is a critical need for more infrastructure in industrial as well as emerging economies. But there are good reasons why private investment is wary to make strategic investments in this area, and many reasons (including environmental, social, and governance related) why the official community is careful to act. Unless we are going to abandon these concerns, which I’d oppose, there will not be easy investments to fund, which could lead to excessive risk taking. 2. Limited institutional capacity. Instituting a global development agenda—identifying and implementing projects, monitoring against corruption, measuring the impact—takes extraordinary institutional capacity, something that will take decades for the new bank to develop. (Even at the World Bank, we have seen a recent shift to putting more people in country in part to support project implementation.) In the meantime, the pressure to lend will force tough choices. The NDB could piggyback on the investment expertise of others, including the World Bank and IMF, but the political imperative to differentiate will make that difficult. The NDB could of course link in with high quality private investors, but that has its own problems in a world of weak governance and may tend to lead to a narrow range of low-risk, low developmental impact projects (e.g., 5-star hotels) with an even narrower range of trusted co-financing partners. My greater concern in this case would be that the new Bank becomes captured by the finance ministries of the borrowing countries and backdoor fiscal financing for politically popular projects. Conversely, for creditor countries of the new bank, importantly China, the incentives to encourage lending that supports their overseas investment strategy could be profound. 3. Exogenous is in the eye of the beholder. Limiting emergency financing to exogenous, short-term shocks aims to protect the resources of the institution and avoid the charge that it is simply delaying needed adjustment. But of course distinguishing exogenous shocks from those requiring policy adjustment is hard, and the use of its financing to delay adjustment (and avoid the politically contentious approach to the IMF) will be hard to resist. I wouldn’t be surprised to see the CRA have some sort of rule or informal understanding linking drawings above a certain level to an IMF program, but again that limits the uniqueness and potential additionality of the arrangement. 4. Conditionality is hard. Ultimately, if lending by the bank doesn’t stem a crisis, adjustment will be needed, and it’s hard to believe that the institution will be effective at developing and enforcing conditionality. All one needs to do is recall the image of German leaders in 2010-11 telling Greece what reforms were needed, or the U.S. experience with conditionality on AID lending, to be reminded that the record of bilateral conditionality is poor. As painful as the medicine the IMF dispenses is, when adjustment is needed there is an advantage to multilateralizing policy conditionality through the IMF. While notionally this bank is multilateral, for the foreseeable future its view will be dominated by a small number of creditor countries. 5. It is still debt. My presumption is that, in the early days, the political support for the institution will ensure that it is promptly repaid, and if a borrowing country runs into trouble that it will treat its obligations to the NDB/CRA as senior. But that seniority is a de facto political outcome, not enforced by law, and if someday the borrowing countries perceive that there is limited sanction to running arrears the facilities could be quickly exhausted. Discussion of the political motivations for this effort often touch on the taper tantrum, the sharp reversal of capital flows that many emerging markets saw last year after the Federal Reserve began to discuss its exit from non-conventional monetary policies. But the BRICS Bank has been under discussion for at least five years, and the driver for its creation reflects a longer term frustration of the rising powers that its voice is not well heard in the major international financial institutions and decision making groups. In some respects, the criticism isn’t fair, as serious (if imperfect) efforts have been made to give these countries a greater voice through the G20 and other fora. Also, in important respects the World Bank and IMF’s views on policies affecting these countries have changed. For example, on capital controls, the IMF has a much more nuanced view and is willing to support controls in a wide variety of cases, even outside of crisis. The Washington consensus is far from the rigid doctrine its critics contend. Not that the major powers don’t need to do more, a message my colleague Julia Sweig hopes Washington hears. From this perspective, the failure of the U.S. Government to pass IMF reform is all the more tragic, as it fuels initiatives like the BRICS Bank. In addition, I also don’t see much harm in emerging markets in effect buying insurance against adverse shocks, or the development of new institutions as long as they coordinate effectively within the global architecture. But I am less convinced that the BRICS Bank, even if effective, is a game changer for global finance. The U.S. dollar will still be the primary reserve currency in 10 or even 20 years, and U.S. financial institutions and financial centers will continue to anchor global financial markets--as in the past, there will be tremendous inertia, or hysteresis, to the shift to an new reserve currency or financial system. The BRICS Bank may be celebrated today for accelerating that trend away from the dollar, and its intentions are good, but if it doesn’t manage the risk well it could in the end be a setback to those who would like to see a more multipolar world.
  • Europe and Eurasia
    Global Economics Monthly: June 2014
    Bottom Line: Low inflation may be symptomatic of deeper problems, such as inadequate demand or central bank policy failures. The costs of low inflation could be high for European economies. There is a new Washington consensus, and it consists of a simple message: low inflation threatens the global economy. A weak and disappointing economic recovery feeds the concern, especially at a time when inflation is below targets and near zero in many countries. When did price stability change from a goal to a problem? Is too little inflation a symptom or cause of what ails us? Throughout the industrial world, debate rages over the causes and meaning of the chronically low inflation in the major industrial economies. Since the end of the Great Recession, central banks have seen inflation fall below their targets, despite unorthodox monetary policy aimed at jump-starting demand. Inflation is well below 2 percent in the Group of Three, or G3 (United States, Japan, and the eurozone), as well as in some Asian emerging markets. Though G3 inflation surveys show expectations anchored around 2 percent, bond yields have fallen this year as market participants bet on very low inflation going forward. These low market interest rates now seem at odds with the surveys. Central banks have responded with rate cuts (European Central Bank), quantitative easing (Bank of Japan), and commitments to keep rates low and raise them only gradually over time (Federal Reserve, Bank of England). In the case of the European Central Bank (ECB), President Mario Draghi has cited the "pernicious negative cycle" of low inflation and tight credit conditions as the central reason for recent easing moves. Whether accurate or not, this line of argument has built a consensus for action on the ECB board. Meanwhile, Federal Reserve governors point to the lack of inflationary pressures as evidence that easy monetary policy contains little risk to price stability. So, while central bankers continue to predict their policies will return inflation to target, there is little doubt that the shortfalls are influencing the policy debate. Low Inflation, Not Deflation There is a venerable body of economic analysis on the pernicious nature of deflation, which is usually defined as the broad-based, self-reinforcing decline in prices across an economy. When a country faces deflation, falling real wages and income weaken demand, dampen investment, and undermine confidence. The Great Depression in the United States and the Japanese experience with deflation after 1990 are often cited as evidence of the high cost of deflation and the challenge of ending it. Deflation was a significant risk coming out of the financial crisis of 2008/2009, and it took determined action by central banks to put those fears to rest. However, aside from a few countries on the periphery of Europe, there is little evidence of actual deflation in the industrial world today. At the same time, the stickiness of prices at near-zero levels is hard to explain. Most analysts expected that inflation would remain low for a while after the crisis, given the depth of the recession and the headwinds to recovery from damaged balance sheets and housing markets. Indeed, the sizeable economic slack that resulted was a central driver of the unconventional monetary policies adopted subsequently. But most public and private forecasters predicted prices would have begun to rise by now as recoveries reduced the amount of underutilized resources in the economy and put upward pressure on wages and goods prices (see Figure 1). Figure 1. Projections Predicted Rising Inflation Rates Sources: Federal Reserve, Eurostat How much should we be concerned about prices rising at around 1 percent annually? After all, while price stability is generally accepted as a good thing, and high inflation clearly destructive, there is little actual evidence that small differences in inflation make a big difference for economic growth. If 2 percent inflation is seen as price stability, is 1 percent inflation less efficient? The answer would appear to depend on the reasons for the shortfall. Low Inflation: Why Worry? One of the concerns regarding low inflation is that the economy is just one shock away from deflation. From this perspective, and given that monetary policy operates with "long and variable lags," some buffer against that risk makes sense. Beyond that, low inflation is perhaps symptomatic of a more fundamental problem of inadequate demand, and reflects the failure of the United States, Europe, and Japan to have a more significant liftoff in growth. A second set of concerns relate to worrisome signals to markets when central banks cannot hit targets. An inability to control the inflation rate could indicate that central banks have the wrong economic model, or that they are underestimating the damage caused by the Great Recession. Over time, missing targets can undermine the credibility of the central bank and the effectiveness of its policies. On the other hand, it is worth remembering that, before the euro, the Bundesbank missed its monetary targets about half the time, yet still was seen as highly credible. One reason why central banks might get the outlook wrong is by misestimating the downward structural pressures that result from globalization and demographic changes. The increasing effect of emerging markets on competition and deflation is widely appreciated, and may continue to exert downward pressure on prices even as growth in these countries' trade shares slows. But there is also a cyclical element to the story. In the case of Europe, I would argue that low inflation reflects a too-tight policy from the ECB and an incomplete monetary union, even after last week's rate cuts. But it is much harder to make the case that the policies of the Bank of Japan (following the introduction of Abenomics in early 2013) and the Fed have been too tight. Indeed, in recent months a number of market analysts have highlighted early indications that U.S. prices are moving up. The International Monetary Fund (IMF) has been in the vanguard, arguing that the costs of low inflation could be high globally, particularly for Europe. The arguments against too-low inflation in Europe are threefold: low inflation raises the real burden of the debt and increases real interest rates (interest rates net of inflation) to levels too high for full employment; it prevents the adjustment of relative prices across the eurozone, delaying the needed improvement in competitiveness and rebalancing of demand toward the periphery; and it can destabilize market expectations for future inflation. Without an ability to adjust their exchange rates against other countries in the currency union, and against the backdrop of extremely high government debt levels coming out of the recession, Europeans face a protracted period of low growth that can justify aggressive action from the ECB. Beyond Europe, prominent economists such as Paul Krugman and Larry Summers argue that there may be a long-term problem of inadequate demand. Citing the "secular stagnation" theory of Alvin Hansen, they argue that as a result of weak long-term growth and demand (in part a result of demographic trends that are shifting down the growth in the labor force), interest rates cannot go low enough in real terms to achieve full employment. Their policy prescription involves easier fiscal policy to boost demand and, perhaps, a Federal Reserve that keeps rates low for longer. It is hard to distinguish structural stagnation, which could be long-lasting, from "headwinds" from the financial crisis, including damaged consumer and bank balance sheets, and weak housing and labor markets. These headwinds will continue to recede as markets heal and balance sheets are repaired. In this regard, the U.S. economy is much further along than Europe, where deleveraging and bank cleanups are far less advanced, notwithstanding the progress made this year with the stress test and asset quality review. Globally, there is some evidence for the headwinds thesis in the stabilization (and in some cases increases) in commodity prices and trade. Both had been weak following the recession, contributing to deflationary pressures. Inflation now looks more likely to be driven by traditional cyclical factors in the future, including slack in labor and product markets. In the United States, we see this shift in a renewed debate over how close we are to full employment, following a series of strong employment reports. Economists are divided over whether continuing high rates of long-term unemployment will continue to exert downward pressure on wages, or whether the figure that matters most is the short-term unemployment rate, which is closing in on levels usually associated with an uptick in inflation. What should be done? Overall, I am drawn to the conclusion that, outside Europe, low inflation is more symptom than cause of low growth. I am sympathetic to the notion that low inflation in normal circumstances makes the policy response to a recessionary shock more challenging, because it is difficult to lower real rates sufficiently. From this perspective, a higher inflation target (Olivier Blanchard and others have called for a 4 percent target) has merit, though it is hard to see how central banks can credibly explain that shift to their publics. Whether there is any hard evidence that a 2 percent inflation target is best, it appears likely that policymakers will have to continue aiming for that level. Fortunately, central bank reflationary policies do appear to be working. With inflationary prospects beginning to diverge across the major regions, this suggests that monetary policies will also diverge—with further easing required in Europe and Japan, and normalization in the United States. Over the longer term, we once again may discover value in low inflation and price stability. Looking Ahead: Kahn's take on the news on the horizon New Rules for Banks Announcements from U.S. regulators, including on the Volcker rule, will put meat on the new regulatory structure; foreign banks are unlikely to be pleased by tight restrictions on proprietary investment. Is Abenomics on Course? Japan's economic package will confirm the coming corporate tax cut, but will likely disappoint those looking for aggressive support for the economy. World Cup Economics A long World Cup run can be bad for a country's gross domestic product. But could an early Brazilian exit this year fuel discontent over poor growth and economic policies?
  • International Organizations
    Ukraine: Now Comes the Hard Part
      Petro Poroshenko’s convincing first-round victory in yesterday’s Ukrainian presidential elections, with 54 percent of the vote, is an important step toward political stability. But hard work lies ahead, as attention now returns to the even-more-daunting task of restoring economic stability. Remember that the political crisis of the last six months began as an economic crisis and had its origins in decades of failed economic policies. Massive fuel subsidies going disproportionately to the wealthy, widespread corruption, and distorted markets all contributed to the rot. These policies were reflected in an overvalued exchange rate, large sustained budget deficits, a rising current account deficit, and a falling foreign exchange reserves. Former President Yanukovych’s decision to accept $12 billion from Russia and repudiate the EU association agreement in late 2013 was an effort to delay the inevitable economic crisis that Ukraine now confronts. The IMF stepped in with a $17 billion reform package at the end of April designed to both provide emergency financing and begin the process of reform. Actions taken prior to IMF approval of its program included floating the exchange rate, an initial increase in energy prices, some other budget measures, and steps to address corruption. While necessary, the additional austerity implied by these measures represents a burden on an economy already in recession. So far, the government has sustained support for pro-Western policies despite the clear economic pain involved. Goodwill towards the new regime, and perhaps the unifying effect of the threat from Russia, have limited opposition to these measures outside of southeast Ukraine. But the new President will have to move quickly to address a number of economic challenges if yesterday’s political achievement is going to translate into a more enduring stability. These include: 1.  Reaching agreement with Russia on energy and debt.  Attention has focused on Russia’s threat to cut off gas deliveries on June 1, but equally important is the price that Ukraine pays. The IMF assumes agreement is reached with Russia on a price for gas in line with global prices at $385/mcm (thousand cubic meters).  It also assumes gas arrears and debt service are paid.  A slightly higher or lower price would be handled through an adjustment to IMF financing, but a significantly higher price for gas would outstrip Western financing and raise serious concerns about fiscal and debt sustainability. 2.  Accelerate the financial and trade flows from the West. The West has actually contributed little relative to headline promises so far, though Europe has accelerated trade benefits from the still-to-be–signed association agreement. The $17 billion pledged by the IMF is supposed to unlock a further $10 billion to $15 billion in funding from the World Bank, EU, and other individual countries, and accelerating those flows will be a critical task. 3.  “Sell” austerity at home. The new government will need to explain to the general public why deeper austerity is needed, and why the measures being taken are being done. The interim government, perhaps reflecting Russia’s threat, had maintained a low profile on economic as well as political grounds. That will need to change. 4.  Renegotiate the IMF program?  When the IMF team returns to Kiev at the end of June, it likely will find an economy far different from the rosy economic projections in the program. Anecdotally, the economy outside of southeast Ukraine looks to have weathered the crisis better than some feared, but there is no doubt that the recent turmoil has imposed material costs. The threat of Russian invasion may have receded, but the crisis is imposing continuing costs on economic activity and investment. Further, it is usually the case in cases like this that fiscal revenue falls, not just because of falling growth but also because of increased tax avoidance. The program is not asking for a lot of fiscal austerity—just two percent of GDP in measures (and the deficit actually widens in the short term with the decline in output). But activity is likely to be lower, and debt higher, than projected. The costs of the financial sector bailout are still not clear, and could be higher than the government is assuming. The new government will likely make the case that a more gradual fiscal adjustment, coupled with additional spending on social services, would be more sustainable. I have sympathy for that argument, though Ukraine’s past record of failed programs creates unsurprising skepticism. And who will pay, official creditors or creditors who may be asked to restructure their claims? The IMF is scheduled to disburse $1.4 billion as soon as July 25, and again at end September. Success will require strong governance, and substantial support from the West.  It will not come cheap, and it will take time.  But some early success may be essential to sustaining public support over a difficult coming period.  
  • Europe
    IMF/World Bank Spring Meetings: Three Questions
    The IMF/World Bank spring meetings start today, with a broad agenda and amidst significant global uncertainty.  A good discussion of the agenda is here  and of the Fund’s view is here.  Here are three questions on which I am looking for news, and perhaps even answers. Have we lost confidence in our global growth story? IMF’s global outlook is reasonably sanguine:  the IMF forecasts global growth to average 3.6 percent in 2014--up from 3 percent in 2013--and to rise to 3.9 percent in 2015, led by a solid U.S. recovery. They argue that global headwinds from the great recession are receding, allowing monetary policy—both conventional and unconventional—to normalize. Yet the hallway discussion will be on the new threats to global economy, most notably geopolitical tensions with Russia and in Asia, and what policymakers need to do to prepare.  Most significantly, an intensification of sanctions against Russia could have significant effects on trade and investment, and cause substantial deleveraging in global financial markets. With fiscal authorities for the most part having limited room to offset this shock, contingency planning likely will focus on central bank monetary policy and liquidity facilities (e.g., swap lines). Is this enough? Beyond the evident cyclical risks, a broader question is whether we are too optimistic about trend growth.  In the emerging markets in particular, optimism about growth and convergence has been tempered by weakening performance and more adverse external conditions (e.g., capital outflows, falling export demand due to lower China growth).  From this perspective, the taper tantrum of last year is a false issue (though some emerging market policymakers will still raise it for domestic political purposes); communication is good and the Fed is well aware of the implications of its policies on the world (though they are always cautious in talking about their systemic responsibilities given their legal dual mandate on price stability and employment).  The real issue is whether domestic policies are supportive of growth aspirations. And if not, is there scope, economic and political (with elections coming up in a number of countries), to change policies to restore the momentum of growth? Or is the emerging market growth model broken? How do we reform the IMF?  It appears that the main headline from these meetings will be a new effort to restart IMF reform. The disappointing refusal of the U.S. Congress to pass the IMF reform package will do long-run damage to America’s soft power and the ability to build consensus in difficult crisis resolution issues. But what is the solution? Ted Truman has an interesting idea for the Fund to end-run the U.S. Congress  but I think going around legislatures is too politically dangerous in the United States and elsewhere.  Perhaps more reasonable would be to “combine" the 14th and 15th quota review.  Translated, this means that the agreement would be set aside and a new negotiation begun.  The U.S. administration could commit to the negotiation with Congressional approval, deferring Congressional approval for a better day. Will the rising powers be satisfied with an approach that delays them having an appropriate representative voice in the organization? Is low inflation a major global risk?  A few weeks ago, the IMF had a great blog on the risks for Europe from persistently low inflation (“lowflation”).  Their argument was, at its core, that even absent deflation, low inflation  raises real interest rates and the burden of debt, inhibits adjustment, and  weakens demand. While the issue is most salient for Europe, we could ask the question more broadly. Lower China growth and the turn in the commodity cycle is a drag on export prospects of many countries, particularly commodity-exporting emerging markets. Corporate leverage in Europe and emerging markets is dangerously high. High levels of unemployment remain a critical social and economic problem.  Are disinflationary pressures dampening global growth prospects?  
  • Egypt
    Egypt's Solvency Crisis
    Introduction Egypt is experiencing a deep economic crisis. The country's foreign currency reserves are less than half of what they were before the January 2011 uprising, threatening Egypt's ability to pay for food and fuel. Egypt's budget deficit is 14 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) and its overall debt, which is the result of accumulated deficits, is more than the country's economic output. In this difficult economic climate, roughly 45 percent of Egyptians live on less than two dollars per day. Inflation, which reached as high as 12.97 percent after the July 2013 military coup, is currently at 11.4 percent. Tourism revenue—traditionally a primary source of foreign currency along with Suez Canal tolls and remittances from Egyptians working abroad—is less than half of what it was in the last full year before the uprising. Foreign direct investment has dried up outside the energy sector. Unemployment remains high at 13.4 percent. Among the unemployed, 71 percent are between fifteen and twenty-nine years old. This economic weakness makes it politically difficult to address the problems that contribute to a potential solvency crisis because the necessary reforms will impose hardship on a population that is already experiencing economic pain. Despite these problems, the state of Egypt's economy has received less attention since the July 2013 coup d'état because of an influx of financial support from Saudi Arabia, the United Arab Emirates, and Kuwait. Yet Egypt's economy remains shaky and the threat of a solvency crisis lingers. Indeed, the continuation of violence, political protests, and general political uncertainty—even after planned presidential and parliamentary elections—along with a hodgepodge of incoherent economic policies, all portend continuing economic decline. This in turn could create a debilitating feedback loop of more political instability, violence, and economic deterioration, thus increasing the chances of an economic calamity and yet again more political turmoil, including mass demonstrations, harsher crackdowns, leadership struggles, and possibly the disintegration of state power. The Contingency Insolvency is the inability of an entity—a person, corporation, or country—to meet its financial obligations to lenders. It comes in two forms: balance sheet insolvency and cash flow insolvency. The former occurs when an entity has total liabilities whose value exceeds that of its total assets. Egypt is at greater risk of experiencing the latter, meaning that it cannot meet specific obligations as debt payments are due, and thus defaults. Although its causes were different, Greece's sovereign debt crisis that began in 2009 provides a baseline comparison of a heavily indebted country that had periods of macroeconomic performance, but ultimately was unable to meet its obligations. The overall picture of the Egyptian economy is deeply worrying. Egypt's foreign currency reserves stand at approximately $16 billion to $17 billion, not all of which are liquid. This means that Egypt is just above the $15 billion critical minimum threshold of foreign reserves, which is the amount required to cover costs of food and fuel for approximately three months. Chart 1. Egypt's Foreign Exchange Reserves Due to the unsettled and violent political environment, tourism dropped sharply in 2013. In early 2014, Minister of Tourism Hisham Zazou told the newspaper Al-Hayat that "2013 was the worst year on record for Egypt's tourism industry." Foreign and domestic investment also declined, in comparison to the five years before the January 2011 uprising. In addition, Egypt's central bank announced a cut in interest rates with little warning in late 2013, as part of an effort to spur domestic investment. This makes good economic sense, but the move is also potentially inflationary, putting pressure on the currency and foreign reserves as well as on Egyptian consumers. Government debt is 89.2 percent of GDP and overall debt is more than 100 percent of GDP. It is important to note that the national debt and fiscal deficit are particularly problematic for Egypt because of its debt rating (even though it was recently upgraded from CCC+ to B-). Unlike the United States, Germany, or Canada, each of which has significant levels of debt, it is costly for Egypt to finance its deficit and debt through borrowing. As a result, Egypt has financed its deficit through domestic borrowing from public sector banks and the central bank. According to Fitch Ratings, "bank claims on the government account for 67% of total bank assets." Immediately following Mohammed Morsi's ouster, Saudi Arabia, the Emirates, and Kuwait committed $12 billion to Egypt. The Gulf countries have committed an additional $8 billion as of early 2014. The Egyptians can also tap into an $8.8 billion grant from the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) that dates back to the 1990s. This assistance is intended to provide budget relief, replenish foreign currency reserves, finance construction projects, pay for the production of medicines, and make petroleum resources available (though fuel rationing continues). For all of these resources, however, Gulf assistance has provided Egypt with only a bare minimum of relief. For example, there is still an estimated annual $10 billion gap in financing the government deficit. There are two reasons why infusions of more money from foreign donors will not fix Egypt's economic problems. First, by financing new spending with grants from the Gulf, Egypt is merely shifting fiscal problems into the near future. Second, receiving more assistance only masks problems that are rooted in irrational and conflicting economic policies. These policies—including food and fuel subsidies, a still-robust state-owned sector, and a tax policy that does not produce enough revenue—are the primary reasons why the government burns through anywhere from an estimated $1 billion to $1.5 billion of its reserves per month paying for critical needs and defending the currency. The policies place significant pressure on the government's budget. Subsidies, for example, account for 29.67 percent of the government's expenditures. Chart 2. Egypt's Subsidies Yet, the prevailing political uncertainty in Egypt makes it difficult for the government to undertake meaningful reform. The rigidity of Egypt's system of subsidies, for example, is a critical component of the Egyptian social safety net and an important means of political control. Making fundamental changes to subsidies risks mass demonstrations similar to the 1977 Bread Riots, which erupted after Anwar Sadat proposed alterations to food subsidies consistent with recommendations from the International Monetary Fund (IMF). Despite pledges to reduce the government budget deficit to 10 percent of GDP (it reached 14 percent of GDP in 2012–2013), Egyptian officials have increased spending, including on a stimulus program and the introduction of a minimum wage for public sector workers. Yet, it will be difficult to reduce the deficit while pursuing expansionary fiscal policy. The new minimum wage of $172 per month will put further pressure on the budget. Likewise, additional economic stimulus packages will also increase the deficit. It may very well be that an expansionary fiscal policy is necessary, but the Egyptians do not have the means to finance it. In addition, despite much discussion of subsidy reform and some rather modest headway in means-testing energy subsidies, the effort to address this major problem is more theoretical than real. Distortions in the markets for bread, fruit, and vegetables also persist, but are unlikely to be addressed for political reasons. This type of ad hoc policymaking seems aimed more at temporarily mollifying various interests than establishing economic sustainability and is a sign of the leadership's inability to arrest Egypt's economic decline. The foreign reserves problem is exacerbated by Egypt's sensitivity to changes in commodity prices, given that it is a net importer of oil and natural gas and the world's largest importer of wheat. Consider, for example, a run-up in wheat prices, which are critically important given the Egyptian government's commitment to subsidizing bread. An external shock such as drought, extreme heat, wildfires, political instability, or some other cause of a poor harvest in the major global producers—the United States, Canada, Australia, Ukraine, and Russia—would result in a substantial increase in the global price of wheat, placing an additional burden on Egyptian finances. Another potential shock is the rapid depreciation of the Egyptian pound, resulting from any number of factors including the central bank's decision to cut interest rates, a move by foreign donors to decrease (though not end) their financial assistance to Cairo, or an unforeseen political event that encourages Egyptians to change pounds into dollars. With limited foreign reserves at its disposal, Egypt's central bank would be hard-pressed to defend the currency, resulting in inflation. Under these circumstances, Egypt might be forced to print money, which would compound the inflationary pressures associated with depreciation. No single event alone would trigger a solvency crisis, but multiple political and economic factors already present could potentially make Egypt default. Saudi Arabia, the United Arab Emirates, and Kuwait seem willing to underwrite Egypt with few conditions or limits. Yet, Gulf support may not be sustainable over the longer term, if Egypt's financial needs prove to be greater than anticipated, if political rifts develop with Cairo, if the priorities of the Saudis, Emiratis, and Kuwaitis change, or if any of the three Gulf states face budgetary or political pressures of their own. A reduction or suspension of the aid would certainly precipitate a solvency crisis. The most likely trigger for insolvency, however, is the continuation of current economic policies, which place significant and ultimately unsustainable pressure on the country's finances. Egyptians may enjoy a respite with an upcoming presidential election and the false sense of "turning the corner" it might provide. As the Egyptian government continues to pursue incoherent fiscal and monetary policies, the foreign reserves situation will deteriorate, rendering Egypt insolvent. The onset of this crisis may be long in the making, but its effects will likely be felt quickly. Egyptians would once again be unable to buy fuel, medicine, basic foodstuffs, and other important goods. Such a situation could potentially bring large numbers of people into the streets in opposition to the government. Given the tendency of Egypt's internal security services to respond to demonstrations with too much force—which encourages people to join protests—rallies could spread throughout the country. This revolutionary bandwagon could overwhelm the government, but this time it may be even more difficult for the military to maintain stability and its control of the state. The Gulf states would likely again provide financial support to Cairo to avoid this outcome. However, infusions of aid will neither resolve nor mitigate the adverse effects of economic policies that have led to the solvency crisis. Warning Indicators The following warning indicators should help U.S. officials and other observers determine whether Egypt is facing an imminent solvency crisis: The government tightens currency controls. Should the government prevent individuals and firms from transferring certain amounts of hard currency out of Egypt, it would be a clear signal that Egyptian officials are concerned about the country's solvency. Beginning in January 2014, individuals can transfer up to $100,000 in hard currency out of the country, which is a relaxation of previous controls established during the Supreme Council of the Armed Forces–led transitional period after former president Hosni Mubarak's ouster that limited transfers to $100,000 over a lifetime. Egyptian officials have left open the possibility of changing exchange-rate controls in 2015. A tightening of restrictions would preserve foreign currency, but at the expense of scaring away current and potential investors. The government restructures its debt, forcing banks to buy debt instruments. Restructuring government debt would require the Egyptian government to force banks to exchange old debt for new debt or to impose new taxes on their returns. Imposing debt restructuring on the banks would place additional pressure on Egypt's financial sector. In addition, the extent to which authorities are forcing banks to buy bonds and treasury bills to finance the deficit, or the Central Bank of Egypt is financing government purchases, indicates that the country is nearing a solvency crisis. Egypt's arrears rise. Observers should pay careful attention to Egypt's arrears. A rise in Cairo's overdue debts is perhaps the clearest indicator that Egypt is headed toward insolvency. A rise in arrears may be the result of settling certain obligations before others, but it does indicate that default is a strong possibility. Egypt suddenly demonstrates an interest in an International Monetary Fund standby agreement. The Egyptian government is counting on Gulf assistance to float the economy. In addition, an IMF standby agreement is a politically difficult proposition for Cairo. Thus, although signing a deal with the Fund seems—from the outside—to be prudent, it is politically difficult. Under these circumstances, a sudden Egyptian interest in negotiating with the IMF would indicate that Cairo is worried about its solvency Implications for U.S. Interests Insolvency in Egypt would damage U.S. interests, threatening the safety of American citizens and U.S. property while putting U.S. business assets at risk. The largest American investor in Egypt, the Houston-based oil exploration and production company Apache Corporation, reduced its exposure to Egypt by bringing on Sinopec as a partner in late 2013. Egypt's total share of Apache's overall production declined from 26 percent to 16 percent. Other large multinationals such as Coca-Cola continue to operate in Egypt with little disruption, but an economic crisis and the concomitant political instability might negatively affect those firms. Breakdown in Egypt would also affect U.S. forces and military posture in the Persian Gulf. The U.S. Navy places a premium on expedited transit through the Suez Canal. In addition, multiple daily U.S. Air Force overflights through Egyptian airspace en route to the Gulf could be curtailed or halted as a result of an Egyptian collapse. Finally, the United States and other interested parties, including European and Gulf states, would confront a major humanitarian crisis in Egypt, which would have trouble securing basic necessities for its eighty-six million people. An economic collapse triggered by insolvency and the subsequent political fallout in Egypt would also threaten Israeli security. The northern Sinai, where the military is fighting a low-level insurgency, has become a staging ground for attacks on Israel's southern cities and towns. If one of those attacks killed or injured large numbers of Israelis, it would force the Israelis to respond, potentially compromising the Egypt-Israel peace treaty—a pillar of U.S. policy in the Middle East. Preventive Options Although the United States has its own fiscal problems, it can still pursue several discrete measures that could help prevent a solvency crisis and potentially stave off Egypt's economic collapse. Provide loan guarantees. The United States, European Union (EU), and Asian allies could pool resources and provide loan guarantees for Egypt. The United States has successfully pursued a similar policy in Jordan. Loan guarantees offer two primary benefits to donors and recipients: they are an effective way of leveraging large amounts of money with a limited commitment of resources—unless Egypt defaults—and they allow Cairo to borrow on commercial markets at significantly lower interest rates than a country with a B- rating would otherwise be able to obtain. Recognizing the sensitivity in the United States to offering the Egyptians what some consider a "blank check," there would need to be a prior agreement with Cairo that the loans would be used for Egypt's greatest needs, specifically food, fuel, and medicine. There are also some practical problems associated with loan guarantees. The loan guarantees involve expenditures that would require authorization from the U.S. Congress and subsequent spending cuts to offset the resources spent guaranteeing loans for Egypt. In addition, even with the backing of the United States, Europe, China, Japan, South Korea, and other global economic actors, Egypt's ability to borrow on commercial markets with its poor rating represents a significant challenge. Relieve the debt. Egypt's foreign debt is $47 billion as of the end of January 2014, of which $3.5 billion is owed to the United Sates. This external debt is relatively small as a percentage of GDP compared to domestic debt. Still, it could send an important signal to other holders of Egyptian debt if the United States took steps to relieve Cairo's financial burden. In 2011, the United States sought to "swap" Egypt's dollar-denominated debt for payment in Egyptian pounds that would then be used to pay for programs like education and youth employment. This scheme was dropped over objections from the Egyptian government. But the Obama administration proposed a debt swap for good reasons—specifically, to encourage Egyptians to invest in areas that were in dire need of resources and would benefit Egypt in the future. Given developments over the last three years and the state of the economy, relieving Egypt's debt to the United States is still prudent. It is important to note that debt relief, like loan guarantees, requires congressional authorization and spending cuts to offset this assistance, though it would be less than the amount of the debt. Pay down domestic debt. The United States should encourage the Egyptians to use foreign assistance to pay down public domestic debt, which stands at $240 billion, instead of increasing expenditures on subsidies, a minimum wage, and a stimulus package that Cairo has no way to finance. Keep the lights on. Although not as acute as they were in the spring and early summer of 2013, fuel shortages and blackouts in Egypt continue. In early June 2013, the Saudis and Egyptians signed an agreement to share energy by linking the two countries' power grids. This is a step toward relieving shortages, but the project will take two to three years to complete. Gulf fuel transfers since the coup have helped mitigate the problem, but demand remains high and Egypt's production of natural gas has declined. Rather than leaving the issue to Saudi Arabia, the United Arab Emirates, and Kuwait, the United States could establish a consortium of international donors to facilitate Egypt's import of the natural gas necessary to generate electricity, freeing up money in the budget to focus on longer-term threats to Egypt's economic stability. Once again, the U.S. Congress might be reluctant to assist Egypt in this manner given the need for budget cuts with any new expenditure. Mitigating Options In the event that Egypt defaults on its debts, the United States has several options to alleviate the consequences and reduce the likelihood of a political collapse in the country and its attendant strategic and humanitarian problems. Support the military. In the event of a solvency crisis and its attendant political consequences, it is likely the military would intervene in politics. The United States should offer political and diplomatic support to the senior command to prevent Egypt from becoming a failed state. This means recognizing any new government that results from such an intervention and using Washington's diplomatic clout with allies in the region, Europe, and Asia to do the same. It will also entail additional economic support. American support for the Egyptian military, along with Washington's response to the 2013 coup, is controversial in both Egypt and the United States. The unpleasant fact, however, is that the armed forces remain the only truly national institution Egypt has. Its civilian political class lacks dynamism, and its other government ministries barely function and command few resources. In the event of insolvency, the officer corps will be the only relatively organized and coherent force capable of preventing a descent into chaos. Provide immediate infusions of financial assistance. The United States could establish an Egypt Contact Group so that wealthy countries can extend immediate financial assistance to Egypt. The Group would include the United States, EU, major Asian countries, and the Gulf states. As noted above, Egypt could potentially experience a solvency crisis even with assistance from wealthy countries in the Gulf, which is why it is incumbent on the rest of the world to marshal even greater resources to refloat the Egyptian economy. Restore food aid. Food aid to Egypt ended in 1992; it could be started again. Egypt is particularly sensitive to changes in the global price of wheat. Indeed, between 2009 and 2011, food insecurity in Egypt increased by 3 percent. Economic collapse would only increase food insecurity. Recommendations The United States has limited diplomatic and economic tools at its disposal to help the Egyptians. Even if Washington could bring billions to bear on Egypt's economic difficulties, it would do little to mitigate the underlying economic problems that place the country at risk of a solvency crisis. It is up to the Egyptians to undertake reforms to forestall this outcome. Given the fact that the Egyptians have done little in this regard, a solvency crisis is entirely plausible. Consequently, the United States has a strategic responsibility to do what it can in Egypt to prevent the causes of insolvency and its attendant political consequences. In addition to implementing the preventive measures outlined above, the Obama administration should do the following: Work with the U.S. Congress to support Egypt with additional aid. There is resistance in Congress to increasing aid to Egypt. But the $250 million in economic support funds is a paltry sum given Egypt's needs. Again, additional funds will not by themselves resolve Egypt's economic problems, but they will give Egyptian policymakers time to undertake politically controversial reforms. Ideally, the United States would condition this new assistance on much-needed economic reform. This is unlikely to work given that Gulf aid is available without explicit prerequisites, which is why Washington should focus its diplomatic efforts on convincing wealthy Arab states and others to encourage Cairo to undertake meaningful reforms. Still, the Obama administration and legislative branch should take a long view of Egypt; while the status of Egypt's Copts, the government's commitments to human rights and democracy, and Egypt's relations with Israel are important, they are secondary to a solvency crisis that threatens Egypt's collapse, which would surely affect all of the issues over which Congress has expressed concern. Establish an interagency Egypt crisis monitoring group. The U.S. State Department, Central Intelligence Agency, Department of Defense, and Treasury Department should increase their surveillance of the Egyptian economy in order to better prepare the government to respond to an Egyptian crisis. This interagency group would be particularly important given that the Egyptian government tends not to be forthcoming with accurate economic data. The United States should share its information and findings with friendly governments that are also committed to preventing an Egyptian solvency crisis. Push others to do their part. The United States should prepare for the moment when Egypt's economic problems overwhelm even Gulf-based aid and use its diplomatic clout in other parts of the world to secure additional assistance for Egypt. Countries in Asia and Europe are understandably reluctant to commit resources to Cairo without Egyptian policy reform, which is why Washington should also encourage Egyptian officials to resume negotiations with the IMF. The Fund should play an important role in assisting the next government to redraw Egypt's social contract in a way that is both politically acceptable at home and can command the strong support of the rest of the world. Central to the plan is the development of a bridge to a new system that better targets subsidies while providing a safety net for those who no longer qualify for subsidized goods and one that establishes a transparent and regular mechanism of price and subsidy changes, thus reducing their political toxicity. This means that foreign donors will need to accept a slower reduction in subsidies than under a conventional IMF program in order to increase the likelihood that Egyptians can make headway on reforms in a coordinated and more coherent manner. Conclusion Egypt is perilously close to becoming insolvent. Despite Gulf assistance, the combination of the country's economic needs, the legacies of Cairo's incoherent economic policies of the past along with their continuation today, the political challenges to economic reform, and the potential for exogenous economic shocks all make a solvency crisis a significant possibility. The United States and its allies in the Persian Gulf, Europe, and Asia should be prepared for this outcome. Increased attention to this issue among policymakers and plans to prevent or mitigate the consequences of Egypt's default are focused principally on infusions of additional aid. This will certainly help Egypt to purchase food, fuel, and other critical goods, but external aid will not resolve the problem. At best, it will give Egyptian policymakers some breathing room and thus an opportunity to undertake economic reforms.
  • Budget, Debt, and Deficits
    Ukraine and IMF: Step Forward Now
    The IMF announced today that it has reached an agreement in principle on a two-year program (stand-by arrangement) with Ukraine. The headline numbers are $14-18 billion of IMF money and overall financing of $27 billion, which is lower than some had hoped, but don’t be fooled. This is a three-to-six month program, designed to meet Ukraine’s critical near-term financing needs and to get reforms going. Both are essential tasks, and rightfully the focus. The program will be revised (and likely boosted) after elections. It will be at that point that thorny issues like debt restructuring will be addressed. The program lays out a roadmap for how the official community would like to see Ukraine reform, and how it expects the economy to respond. That’s a useful anchor for expectations, and an important signal of support for Ukraine, but given the extraordinary political and economic uncertainty it is a wish more than forecast. Still, the program shows IMF leadership at a critical time, and in that sense, is essential as a complement to sanctions and as a Western response to Russian aggression in Ukraine. A few points about the program: 1. Tough up front actions Prior actions—those things Ukraine must do before the IMF Board approves the program in April and makes the first disbursement, reportedly includes: (i) a commitment to maintain a flexible exchange rate system, (ii) increases in energy prices by 50 percent, (iii) passage of a budget for 2014, and (iv) a commitment to anti-corruption legislation and improving the business climate. Fixing the banking system is a fifth pillar of the program but it’s too early to know how bad the hole will be. I would have preferred less austerity now, but a full program apparently was the only way to get enough money to Ukraine in the near term. The question now will be the domestic reaction to these measures (which will no doubt be blamed on the former government). The IMF has asked for as much austerity as is reasonable to expect, and perhaps more. 2. Keeps the lights on The IMF first disbursements aim to trigger the release of $6 billion to $8 billion over the next several months from the EU, the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) and the World Bank. Passage also looks to be imminent for the $1 billion U.S. loan guarantee, along with a small amount of bilateral assistance. That should be just enough to provide critical government services (including safety net payments), service its foreign-currency denominated debt, and purchase gas till the summer. Press reports suggest those payments total $6.2 billion in the second quarter. What is unusual here is that the IMF has agreed to a set financing gap and allowed its stated financing to vary between $14-18 billion depending on other support.  That makes sense given the uncertainty, but it’s troubling that at the same time the IMF is stepping into the breech, other creditors seem to be stepping back.  This morning, there are reports that European aid other than "emergency" assistance may be delayed until after elections.  The IMF should not be alone in the financial vanguard. 3. Optimism on the economy The program reportedly assumes a decline in GDP of 3 percent this year (many private economists expect a decline or 5 percent or more) despite substantial fiscal measures and a deepening crisis. The central government deficit will decline, but the overall deficit (including the gas company) should continue to be in the range of the 9 ½ percent of GDP figure from last year (it would have been over 10 percent without new measures). 4. No PSI, for now It appears that there is no debt restructuring (private sector involvement, or PSI) planned at this time. That means holders of June 2014 eurobonds should be happy. But if I’m right that there will need to be a rethink of the program in the summer, the reprieve may be short lived. Even ahead of that, we shouldn’t underestimate the domestic political desire for burden sharing, if not through a restructuring then through a rollover of bank lines (Vienna Initiative) or new loans from wealthy Ukrainians (e.g., a friends of Ukraine donors conference or patriot bond). So watch the reaction domestically to the sharp rise in energy prices to consumers. One more point:  the IMF announcement notes that "With no market access at present, large foreign debt repayments loom in 2014-15."  We are warned. Markets should respond well to the news. Over the past few weeks, markets have rallied on signals that the IMF program was near and drew support from hopes that Russia would make no further moves against Ukraine. In that sense, I see a substantial disconnect between the markets and many on the political side, who seem far more worried that we could be at an early stage of an escalating confrontation between Russia and the West. That suggests that, at a minimum, markets remain vulnerable to adverse news from Ukraine in coming weeks.