Economics

Competitiveness

  • China
    Innovation, Espionage, and Chinese Technology Policy
    Adam Segal testifies before the House Foreign Affairs Subcommittee on Oversight and Investigations about Chinese cyber espionage and China's desire to reduce its dependence on the West for advanced technologies.
  • Economics
    Reviving Competition in Mexico’s Economy
    In trying to explain why Mexico isn’t growing quickly, or "why it isn’t rich" as Gordon Hanson puts it in a great paper, there is much talk about economic concentration -- the monopolies and oligopolies that dominate the economy. They spread beyond just telecommunications and media – the most obvious and maligned sectors. In cement, one company alone controls almost 90% of the market. In bread, tortillas, soft drinks, hospitals, and glass production just one company controls at least 70% of the market. This doesn’t even consider those areas still under state control, such as energy and electricity. This wasn’t always the case. Looking back at the 1960s and 1970s -- when the Mexican economy was much more closed and the state more involved -- its markets were arguably more open, at least in terms of competition. At least four major firms competed in even the most concentrated sectors (granted, those not consigned to state-owned monopolies). This internal competition was at least in part behind the rising competitiveness of Mexico’s economy – as measured by total factor productivity (TFP). Mexico’s TFP, a measure of an economy’s long-term technological dynamism, rose steadily through the 1960s and 70s, comparing favorably to the United States and the so-called Asian tigers. It began to fall in the early 1980s (in conjunction with its debt crisis and economic opening). It hasn’t recovered since. Mexico's Total Factor Productivity (relative to U.S. TFP) compared to Latin America and Asian Tigers (Source: Augusto de la Torre and Ana Cusolito, "Competition and Economic Growth," The World Bank, 2009) The fact is that while Mexico’s economy opened to the world, vital sectors within it closed themselves off from competition. This isn’t to say that Mexico should try to return to protected markets - that would just make matters worse. But it does suggest that the dominance of just one or two firms across so many areas of the economy hasn’t always been a part of its past – and agreeing with the consensus out there, it shouldn’t be part of its future.
  • United States
    Infrastructure Investment and U.S. Competitiveness
    How can the United States improve its aging infrastructure to maintain its global economic competitiveness? Four experts offer their suggestions and discuss the implications of inaction.
  • China
    The Not-So-Free Market for Clean Energy Technology
    The New York Times “Room for Debate” asked seven smart experts whether the United States can compete with China on green technology. Their responses, published yesterday, are well worth reading. I worry, though, that they reflect a peculiar, and increasingly unproductive, debate. The four participants who aren’t academic economists all offer some variation on the claim that green energy can be a central driver of economic growth, and that the United States thus needs a green industrial strategy. I’ve explained on many occasions why I’m skeptical of both assertions. Green technology is important, but there isn’t compelling evidence that it will have big direct consequences for economic growth. I suspect that’s what motivated the three academic economists who were invited to contribute to all offer variations on a similar theme in response: in a free market, countries specialize in areas where they have comparative advantage; as a result, everyone wins. If China’s gaining market share in certain technologies, they argue, that’s ultimately good for all. Here’s the massive problem with that: The global economy is nowhere close to being a free market. Barriers to trade and investment abound. Governments frequently use their power to promote favored firms and discriminate against others. The current situation isn’t the consequence of the free market. Saying “the free market works” is no way to defend it. I have a new article up at Foreign Policy that comes to more mixed conclusions. The central point of my piece is that we ought to stop freaking out so much about supposed Chinese strength in clean energy. Like the academic economists in the New York Times debate, I’m sensitive to the fact that a lot of cleantech migration to China is the result of genuine comparative advantage, and thus doesn’t deserve to be demonized. But I also argue that that’s not the whole picture: in some cases, the shift is the result of anticompetitive Chinese policies that are anything but economically beneficial for the world. That’s not the sort of behavior that should be supported or ignored in the name of free market sensibilities.
  • Mexico
    Beyond NAFTA: Raising Cross-Border Competitiveness
    Play
    Experts forecast the developments of U.S.-Mexico relations as a result of the new U.S. Congress, the need for Mexico to increase foreign direct investment in the face of investor insecurity caused by violence and organized crime. This session was part of a CFR symposium,200 Years of U.S.-Mexico Relations: Challenges for the 21st Century,which was made possible through generous support from the Consulate General of Mexico in New York, the Mexican Cultural Institute of New York, and CFR's Civil Society, Markets, and Democracy Initiative.
  • Energy and Climate Policy
    Energy Innovation
    Overview Low-carbon technology innovation and diffusion are both essential aspects of an effective response to climate change. Studying China, India, and Brazil, Michael A. Levi, Elizabeth C. Economy, Shannon K. O’Neil, and Adam Segal examine how innovation in low-carbon technologies occurs and how the resulting developments are diffused and adopted. This report zeros in on a critical tension: the United States' interests in encouraging the spread of technology to reduce emissions can clash with efforts to strengthen its own economy. This tension has traditionally been the province of debates over “technology transfer” and intellectual property rights; this study goes beyond those debates to look at the complete innovation system. The authors begin by exploring each major emerging economy in four different dimensions. First, they examine how efforts to create and manufacture low-carbon technologies do and do not stimulate efforts to deploy those technologies at home. Second, they assess how government policies affect countries' abilities to absorb technologies, looking at policies that create markets, invest in innovation, protect intellectual property rights (IPR), and affect trade and investment barriers. Third, they examine how the economic structure of each major emerging economy affects the country’s ability to respond to climate change through innovation and foreign technology absorption. Fourth, they examine each country's ambitions for technology and product exports, which affect the degree to which U.S. commercial interests are helped or hindered by the spread of technology. The report then assesses a range of policies and offers recommendations. These are aimed at boosting domestic investment in innovation, strengthening active government promotion of technology transfer and diffusion, and promoting an open international system conducive to the commercial spread of technology. Recommendations address IPR, trade and investment rules, government support for research, development and demonstration, standard setting, technology cooperation centers, and multilateral institutions, among other areas. The study also includes detailed case studies of wind technology in all three countries, clean coal in China and India, electric vehicles in China, solar energy in India, and biofuels and deforestation in Brazil.
  • Energy and Climate Policy
    Why Letting Manufacturers Opt In to Cap-and-Trade Could Increase Emissions
    Senators from manufacturing states have been among the most skeptical of cap-and-trade legislation. One would expect, then, that they’d be thrilled by the prospect of utility-only cap-and-trade, which would explicitly exclude manufacturing facilities. But not so. Here’s E&E Daily this morning: “Sen. Sherrod Brown (D-Ohio), meanwhile, stressed earlier this week that manufacturers must have the choice to opt in to a carbon pricing system and that he is working on legislation that would allow them to do that under a utility-only bill.” Why, after resisting cap-and-trade, do manufacturers suddenly want in? Utility-only cap-and-trade would, like economy-wide cap-and-trade, increase the cost of the electricity used by many manufacturers. Under previously proposed economy-wide schemes, many manufacturers would have received rebates equal to or greater than those increased costs. Under most plausible utility-only schemes, most energy-intensive manufacturers will receive substantially smaller rebates, and some (such as those who are in states where electricity prices are not heavily regulated) may receive nothing. Utility-only is thus not a free pass for manufacturers. These manufacturers are looking for “opt-in” provisions that would help cover some of their increased electricity bills. Yes, by joining the cap-and-trade system, they would see their costs increase further (because they’d pay for their own direct pollution too). But they’re looking for a deal that more than pays them for that extra cost. Hence the sudden interest in being part of the system. What does this all mean environmentally? An well-designed opt-in scheme would probably strengthen the headline target of a cap-and-trade bill. That’s because the cap would be increased only by a fraction of the emissions of any facility that decided to opt in. Imagine, for example, that a plant with 100,000 tons of annual emissions chose to join. The 2020 target would probably increase by only 83% of that, or 83,000 tons. That would force 17,000 tons of reductions under the cap, either at the manufacturing plant, or in the (already covered) utility sector. That said, to the extent that an opt-in scheme preferentially attracts those plants with the easiest potential reductions (which the most likely outcome), those reductions might be meaningless (i.e. they might be reductions that would have occurred anyhow, even without cap-and-trade). Indeed it is very possible that some of the opt-ins would actually weaken the environmental result. Imagine, for example, that the 100,000 ton plant expects its emissions to drop by 20,000 tons by 2020. It opts in to cap-and-trade and follows through with its plans. The utility-only cap is about 2 billion tons of CO2 in 2020. The opt-in expands that by 83,000 tons, to 2,000,083,000 tons. 80,000 tons of permits are used up by the manufacturing plant. That leaves 2,000,003,000 tons of permits for the utilities, which is more than they started with. As a result, the carbon price drops, and emissions are reduced by less than they would have been without the opt-in. Will this sort of thing happen? It depends entirely on how any opt-in provisions are designed. I have been skeptical of claims that badly-designed cap-and-trade could increase emissions. (Perhaps hostile is a more accurate word than skeptical.) Those claims tend to ignore economics. But a badly designed opt-in scheme could be an exception. Legislators should be careful to ensure that it isn’t.
  • Global
    International Competitiveness and Education: A Conversation with Arne Duncan
    Play
    Recent studies have concluded that the United States continues to fall behind other countries in student achievement, particularly in the areas of math and science. Please join Secretary of Education Arne Duncan to discuss the future of U.S. education policy and its implications for international competitiveness and national security.  
  • Global
    International Competitiveness and Education: A Conversation with Arne Duncan
    Play
    Secretary of Education Arne Duncan speaks about the importance of education to U.S. global competitiveness.
  • United States
    The Tricky Path to U.S. Revival
    President Barack Obama’s first State of the Union address focused heavily, as expected, on domestic economic recovery and reasserting U.S. competitiveness. Six CFR experts noted different aspects of the challenges facing Obama.
  • United States
    McKinsey Executive Rountable Series in International Economics: U.S. Capital Markets Competitiveness: Challenges and Choices
    Play
    The McKinsey Executive Roundtable Series in International Economics is presented by the Maurice R. Greenberg Center for Geoeconomic Studies and the Corporate Program.
  • United States
    U.S. Capital Markets Competitiveness: What are the Right Policies?
    Play
    Watch leading global business experts discuss the challenges to competitiveness in U.S. capital markets as part of the Council's McKinsey Executive Roundtable Series in International Economics.