Blogs

Macro and Markets

Kahn analyzes economic policies for an integrated world.

Latest Post

Headquarters of Sberbank, one of the Russian institutions under U.S. sanctions
Headquarters of Sberbank, one of the Russian institutions under U.S. sanctions REUTERS/Sergei Karpukhin

Have Sanctions Become the Swiss Army Knife of U.S. Foreign Policy?

The Congress takes an important, positive step to reinforce Russian sanctions, but are we at risk of overusing the sanctions tool?

Read More
Budget, Debt, and Deficits
Argentina, Bankruptcy, and Baseball
The lawyers who understand the issues much better than me are excited (here and here) by the latest order from the NY Court of Appeals in Argentina’s long-running battle with holdout creditors.  After a hearing last Wednesday that by most accounts went extremely badly for Argentina (it’s probably not the best strategy to ask a court to overturn a ruling because you plan to ignore it, making it ineffectual), the Court issued an order giving Argentina a chance to propose alternative terms to its creditors.  By March 29, Argentina is ordered to provide “the precise terms of any alternative payment formula and schedule to which it is prepared to commit.” There is a good chance the offer from the Court will not lead to a breakthrough. The commentary from the Court in the order appears to suggest that Argentina must eventually “make current” the holdout’s bonds, which the government has long made it clear it is not prepared to do.  So the window for a deal may be small.  But it’s possible that the government’s response will open the door for an agreement brokered by the court. There is a broader idea here.  Is the court, in the face of a defiant debtor and in an environment where its rulings have limited force due to sovereign immunity, willing to entertain a counterproposal from Argentina? If so, it could be a step towards a principles-based approach to restructuring in the shadow of bankruptcy.  In forming an offer, Argentina must weigh the cost of additional concessions against the improved odds that its offer is accepted.  Can this lead to a mutually acceptable outcome? Some evidence comes from baseball’s approach to arbitration.  In arbitration, the player and the team each make an offer, and the arbitrator chooses one of the final offers.  The idea of this approach was to encourage more negotiated settlements, because the cost of losing would be high.  In fact, it seems the process works.  This year, for the first time since arbitration was introduced in 1974, no baseball player went to arbitration!  Though 133 players filed for arbitration, all subsequently reached agreement with their team before the hearing. As I have discussed in the past, most of the time, market-based exchanges succeed in helping address a country’s debt problems, even if a few holdout creditors remain and subsequently make life difficult for the country. A concern in this case is that, in the effort to get Argentina to the table, the court would create a rigid precedent that swings the pendulum too far towards the creditor and makes it harder to do exchanges in the future.  Baseball’s experience tells us deals can still be done.
Budget, Debt, and Deficits
Sequester, Day 1
Does today feel different?  Did the earth shake?  Packing your lunch rather than buy out? Welcome to the sequester. Another manufactured fiscal crisis has failed to produce smart policies.   The effects of this failure will take time to be felt, a “slow ripple of pain” as Politico puts it in their note on the timing of the cuts.  Furloughs notices have to be sent out, agencies will try and smooth or delay the disruptions to services, and no doubt some of the dire warnings are overdone.  But by April we would see material disruptions to services.  That fact, plus rising public unhappiness, makes the sequester unsustainable on economic or political grounds. The next cliff, the March 27 continuing resolution (CR) funding the government, provides a good opportunity to address the sequester, either by providing greater flexibility to the administration in applying the cuts or by backloading and replacing the cuts with other measures.  If the CR fails to address it, the debate could spill into April or May, when the dislocations from layoffs and cutbacks become more critical and perhaps even bring the debt limit debate back into play. How big a hit? The $85 billion in cuts for FY13 that go into effect today will reduce discretionary appropriations to below 2008 levels.  Defense programs will be cut 13 percent and affected non-defense programs by about 9 percent.  Because these are cuts to budget authority and some programs pay out over several years, the direct effects on government spending this fiscal year will be smaller, around $45 billion.  Macroeconomic Advisers, in a well-publicized and detailed study, estimated the sequester would cut GDP by 0.6 percent of GDP for 2013 (to 2 percent).  By the end of 2014, the sequester would cost 700,000 jobs and raise the unemployment rate to 7.4 percent.  The Fed would delay tightening. On one level, this seems manageable in a $16 trillion economy, relative to the warnings that have preceded it. However, it’s hard to account for the effects of a broader disruption in the provision of basic services and public goods. Long waits for planes, delays in food inspection or medical services, and the like could disrupt activity to a far greater degree than these estimates suggest. Macroeconomic Advisers (2/20/13) Markets appear to have responded to the onset of the sequester by…ignoring it.  Recent volatility has reflected renewed fears for Europe in the wake of Italian elections, uncertainty about Fed policy, and currency wars.  It’s hard to pinpoint an independent sequester effect.  Perhaps this reflects cynicism that Congress will find a way to kick the can. Perhaps, instead, it’s "cliff fatigue". Nonetheless, it’s hard not to conclude that the series of endless fiscal cliffhangers is beginning to have an effect on activity. Recent surveys show consumer confidence has been affected, and business investment delayed, due to uncertainty about fiscal policy. What next? I have previously written that the window for a grand bargain is closing.  Each previous effort has fallen short, leaving scar tissue and distrust that make it more difficult to negotiate the next time.  In addition, the deficit reduction that we have achieved may be taking the pressure off our leaders to deal comprehensively with our fiscal deficit. Three years of fiscal showdowns have produced around $2.7 trillion in budget savings, primarily through new revenue and cuts to discretionary spending programs.  CBO now expects the fiscal deficit to fall below 4 percent next year, and to 2 1/2 percent in FY15.  While this is not enough to fix our long-term fiscal problem, it is enough to stabilize the debt at a little over 70 percent of GDP for the next several years before rising interest rates, an aging population and rising medical costs cause the debt to again rise. I continue to hope that a grand bargain can be reached that addresses entitlements, tax reform and the other fundamental drivers of deficit. It would be far better to address the problem now rather than later when a market revolt or the inescapable math of our fiscal problem produces a crisis.  But if that is not possible, it may be time to recognize that fact and find a way to defuse the sense of constant fiscal crisis.  Let’s fight over immigration, gun control and other key priorities. We need an exit strategy.
Budget, Debt, and Deficits
Three Ways Out of the Sequester
Chris Krueger of Guggenheim Securities today has an excellent piece on how the sequester might be resolved.  A few takeaways: 1.  March 1 is a soft deadline for the sequester; the real cliff is the March 27 deadline for a new continuing resolution (CR) funding the government for the remainder of the year (or, more likely, Friday March 22 so that the congressional Easter recess isn’t disturbed). 2.  The sequester is a slow chokehold, but public discontent is likely to ratchet up sharply, forcing a deal by end March. 3.  There are three central scenarios for fiscal year 2013 in play: (i) using gimmicks and back-loaded cuts to pay down the sequester, as we did for two months in the January 2 fiscal cliff deal; (ii) a modified CR that allows more flexibility in implementing cuts and possibly reduces them; (iii) a “fail-safe” option that leaves cuts in place but provides flexibility in their application. 4.  The deal could cover 1 to 2 months or the rest of the fiscal year.  Chris sees a short-term solution as more likely because the price tag is smaller. My problem with a 1 to 2 month solution is that it involves us in a dangerous game of leapfrog.  Congress made a good decision in January when they passed a bill temporarily suspending the debt limit.  By putting the debt limit behind other cliffs (sequester, CR, fiscal year 2014 budget resolutions), it reduced the risk of a catastrophic mistake on the debt limit and shifted the fight to sounder ground.  The idea was that these other cliffs would produce sufficient savings to justify a longer-term debt limit extension.  A 1 to 2 month sequester punt, if followed by a short term CR (on the same logic that it’s the cheaper and easier deal), leapfrogs the debt limit to the front lines of our budget fight, again.  I worry how many times we can navigate showdowns where the hostage is the government’s credibility and capacity to pay its obligations. More broadly, at some point we need an exit strategy from the repeated cliffs and kicking of the can.  Absent a grand bargain that is increasing unlikely, deficit reduction will only stabilize the debt until the middle of the decade, after which demographics and higher interest rates make the debt rise again.  But given that, it would be better to have a deal soon that gives each side some of what they want, and a strategy that defuses the sense of crisis for a while.  Better to save our energy for immigration, gun control or other important priorities…before the can kicks back.
  • Financial Markets
    The G-7, the G-20 and Exchange Rates
    For those interested in policy coordination and exchange rate policy, last week was both entertaining and informative.  U.S. Treasury official Lael Brainard’s G-20 background briefing last Monday, interpreted by some as signaling a green light to Japan for further yen depreciation in support of growth, was followed by statements that seemed to repudiate, support, then reinterpret the statement. The result was significant volatility in foreign exchange markets.  I suspect that was the opposite of what was intended.  Beyond the noise, events last week signal a policy environment where countries have great latitude to take measures that have significant effects on exchange rates.  “Currency wars” is hyperbole, but it’s capturing something real. On the surface, policy appears unchanged.  The G-7 statement on Tuesday reiterated established policy–a commitment to market determined exchange rates, a call to not target specific rates, and a willingness to act when there are excessive volatility and disorderly movements:   We, the G7 Ministers and Governors, reaffirm our longstanding commitment to market determined exchange rates and to consult closely in regard to actions in foreign exchange markets. We reaffirm that our fiscal and monetary policies have been and will remain oriented towards meeting our respective domestic objectives using domestic instruments, and that we will not target exchange rates. We are agreed that excessive volatility and disorderly movements in exchange rates can have adverse implications for economic and financial stability. We will continue to consult closely on exchange markets and cooperate as appropriate. --Statement by G-7 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors, February 12, 2013.   The G-7 doesn’t always issue statements, so it was reasonable to assume that this time: (1) there was concern that the yen’s depreciation had gone far enough, for now, and that Japan shouldn’t use the bully pulpit to further talk down the currency or use foreign currency instruments to intervene; (2) concern that discussion about “currency wars” was building momentum; and (3) a desire to put down a marker that exchange rate policy coordination is primarily the domain of the G-7, not the G-20 (with U.S.-China exchange rate issues handled bilaterally). In this regard, it succeeded.  The key paragraph from the G-20 communique, along with comments from participants, signaled a tamping down of the debate:   5.  We reaffirm our commitment to cooperate for achieving a lasting reduction in global imbalances, and pursue structural reforms affecting domestic savings and improving productivity. We reiterate our commitments to move more rapidly toward more market-determined exchange rate systems and exchange rate flexibility to reflect underlying fundamentals, and avoid persistent exchange rate misalignments and in this regard, work more closely with one another so we can grow together. We reiterate that excess volatility of financial flows and disorderly movements in exchange rates have adverse implications for economic and financial stability. We will refrain from competitive devaluation. We will not target our exchange rates for competitive purposes, will resist all forms of protectionism and keep our markets open. --G-20 communique, February 16, 2013.   But context matters.  In a world where the major countries are enacting unorthodox policies to spur their economies, where the new Washington consensus allows for a greater role for capital controls and other macro-prudential measures, and where the United States arguably has less leverage on countries’ policies, these words take on different meaning.  My take is that, looking ahead, any country that can make a domestic case for measures that weaken the exchange rate can do so without concern for sanction from the G-7.  The country shouldn’t talk down the currency, or use a foreign currency instrument that specifically targets exchange rates, but otherwise the door is more open than it has been for some time. Of course, the lines on what is acceptable are fuzzy and will be debated.  When monetary operating systems differ, one country’s unorthodox monetary policy is another’s exchange rate intervention.  For example, it appears unacceptable in any circumstance for Japan to buy foreign currency bonds for yen, while at the same time it’s ok for countries to buy mortgage backed securities in their own currency.  Also, while fixing exchange rates is not allowed, China’s commitment to incremental, managed yuan appreciation remains acceptable. If we do have a new policy, it may be first seen in capital controls in emerging markets to stem hot money inflows.   Large scale Quantitative Easing (QE) programs, though motivated by domestic considerations, have the result that some of the newly created money will flow overseas.  This is particularly true when QE creates an expectation of currency depreciation. As these flows make their way to emerging markets, we should expect them to react.  Speculation revolves around Korea and Taiwan, given both stated hot money concerns and the importance of their trade relationship with Japan.  The hot-money story was well captured by Mexican Central Bank Governor Augustin Carstens in Singapore earlier this month (as reported by the Wall Street Journal): "Today my fear is that a perfect storm might be forming as the result of massive capital flows to some emerging-market economies and some strong performing advanced economies," Mr. Carstens said in his speech. "This could lead to bubbles characterized by asset mispricing. [Countries could] then face a reversal in flows as the major advanced economies start exiting their accommodative monetary policy stance." Carstens called for more work on when macroprudential policies should be used to address these concerns.  Carstens has strong market credentials so when he warns of a problem, his words catch attention. It may be that, within the G-20, current monetary policies are broadly appropriate for domestic considerations, and there is little reason in the near term to expect an outbreak of competitive depreciation.  But if pressures continue to build, it may become clearer that the debate over exchange rates has entered a new phase.  
  • Economics
    The Fed, Credit Bubbles, and Exit
    Jeremy Stein’s speech  today–“Overheating in Credit Markets:  Origins, Measurement, and Policy Responses”–provides valuable insight on the issue of credit bubbles that could result as a consequence of current Federal Reserve policy.  As such, it speaks to the upcoming debate over the Fed’s exit strategy.  It’s a must read. Stein’s review of credit markets suggest “we are seeing a fairly significant pattern of reaching-for-yield behavior emerging in corporate credit.”  Even so, that by itself is not a reason for policy to react–in Stein’s view, its when bad credit decisions are combined with excessive maturity transformation that troubles occur. One important contribution of the paper is the tour he takes through credit markets, trying to measure reach-for-yield and maturity extension behavior.  This includes major markets (e.g., high-yield corporate bonds and syndicated-leverage loans), the instruments that fund them (including money market/collateral markets) and other indicators of maturity transformation.  The evidence is mixed, but my read is that, if trends continue, eventually these patterns will become a source of concern.  At a minimum, it points to indicators  that should be followed and that are likely to make their way into Fed discussions. Finally, Stein reviews the debate over whether monetary policy, rather than supervisory/regulatory policy, should be used to deflate bubbles.  His conclusion is that while monetary policy may not be the best tool for the job, it has the important advantage of broad market effect, “reaching into corners” that supervision and regulation cannot. That could be true even if the dual mandate pointed towards a continuation of current accommodative policies.  When you have multiple instruments, you can pursue multiple objectives.  That’s a powerful statement.