Blogs

Macro and Markets

Kahn analyzes economic policies for an integrated world.

Latest Post

Headquarters of Sberbank, one of the Russian institutions under U.S. sanctions
Headquarters of Sberbank, one of the Russian institutions under U.S. sanctions REUTERS/Sergei Karpukhin

Have Sanctions Become the Swiss Army Knife of U.S. Foreign Policy?

The Congress takes an important, positive step to reinforce Russian sanctions, but are we at risk of overusing the sanctions tool? Read More

Budget, Debt, and Deficits
IMF/World Bank Meetings: In Search of a Consensus
This week’s Annual Meetings of the World Bank and IMF will have a lot of discussion but little action.  Here are five things that I anticipate will capture some headlines. Growth is important...but what are you going to do about it?  I suspect that we will hear broad frustration from policymakers about the tepid global recovery.  Most expect a gradual global recovery to below average levels, as the scars from the financial crisis and weak policies constrain growth.  But there isn’t much on the table in terms of macro policies that can be debated and changed, and while there is a lot of structural work to be done (e.g., financial sector and labor market reform) we are unlikely to see much real progress on a growth agenda this week. Infrastructure is (a public) good.  Everyone can agree that there is a critical need for additional infrastructure, but unclear what to do about it.  Private sector projects should be encouraged, but appear limited by legal and commercial considerations, and while there is a clear case for public provision of infrastructure ("public goods"), budgets are constrained and standards (including importantly environmental standards) limit governments’ capacity to respond.  The Fund calls for more efficiency and a push by countries that have the budget space.  Beyond that, the Chinese-led initiative for an Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB), and to a lesser extent the slower-moving BRICs Bank, will be a focus.  There appears to be a great deal of energy behind the AIIB, but it’s hard to imagine it scaling up quickly without risking a major weakening of standards, poor project selection or “capture” by borrowing countries.  Can the AIIB collaborate effectively with the World Bank and Asian Development Bank and avoid fragmentation? Is geopolitical risk a major threat to markets? As I have written, policymakers are concerned by the apparent disconnect between rising geopolitical risk and a benign market outlook.  The concern is legitimate, but there is little consensus that economic policymakers should say or do anything differently.  Still, this discussion will be an important part of the hallway debate.  There are broader questions here about the global economic architecture.  Are we headed towards comprehensive financial sanctions against Russia, and if so, would restrictions on the payments system threaten a basic “public good?” Where is the IMF going on debt policy?  The Fund recently endorsed the introduction of new clauses in debt contracts, addressing the inter-creditor equity problems highlighted by Argentina’s legal battle with its creditors and strengthening the ability of distressed debtors to coordinate with their creditors on a solution.  This is all to the good, though it arguably would have happened even without the Fund’s involvement.  The real challenge— how do we encourage the quick transformation of the existing stock of debt (which doesn’t have the clauses) into new debt—is still to be addressed.  Look for some discussion this week of ways in which the official community can provide a push to efforts to swap old debt for new debt (through market exchanges) with the improved clause. More broadly, the IMF continues to develop the case for new rules governing its lending, including a greater focus on extending the maturity of private debt when it is lending large amounts in risky situations.  I am not convinced that there is a problem in debt markets that needs solving, or that this is the solution.  The debate this week may instead focus on the so-called “systemic exemption,” which gives the major countries the ability to bend Fund rules for lending when systemic issues are in play (e.g., Greece, Ireland).   The IMF would like to constrain or eliminate that rule, and while I’m sympathetic, it is not realistic in my view to expect the major countries to tie their hands regarding how they respond to global crisis. IMF reform (still) stalled.  There is growing international frustration with the failure of the United States to pass the IMF quota and governance reform package.  My read of the environment in the U.S. Congress is that the chances of passage this year are lower than ever before, so the international community will need to begin to talk publicly about what comes next.
Russia
New Energy for Russian Sanctions
Time will tell whether new sanctions on Russia announced by the United States and European Union last week will be a game changer. The most significant development concerns oil, as the new measures go much further than previously understood to shut down ongoing exploration and production of new Russian supply. While triggered by events on the ground in Ukraine, from a policy perspective this is a catch-up action, closing loopholes and bringing market practice more in line with the harsher intent of earlier measures. As such, I view the steps as an incremental, if logical, next step in the effort to punish Russia for its actions in Ukraine. Still, compared to what some energy companies thought they would be allowed to do, the new measures look to be material in terms of their effect on ongoing exploration, development and investment in securing new oil. Descriptions of the new measures are here and here. A few points 1. The Russian invasion of Ukraine, and continued efforts to at a minimum create a frozen conflict, should be seen as the primary trigger for the sanctions. Both U.S. and European officials have stated that these sanctions could be removed if the current peace process takes hold—a 12-step plan that would involve the complete removal of Russian troops and hardware from Ukraine. But few are optimistic on this score. 2. U.S. and E.U. energy sanctions do differ in scope and definition, but the core principle is to make clear that sanctions affect the provision of technology, goods or services for exploration and production of new deep-water, arctic or shale oil. An existing well can still pump, but efforts to develop new sources of oil are broadly affected. The U.S. also goes further than Europe in requiring that U.S. operations affected by the sanctions be wound up in 14 days, and since no major EU companies are drilling in the Arctic it seems the U.S. rules are of central importance. 3. Several commentators have noted that U.S. energy companies had been seen as sidestepping earlier sanctions, and in particular continuing exploration efforts that began prior to sanctions. Exxon’s continued and highly publicized joint venture with Rosneft in the Arctic Circle may have raised the ire of policymakers (apparently, because the rig was already in place, they earlier were able to provide services for the drilling to start—now it appears that is ruled out), but it’s not the primary reason for additional sanctions at this time. 4. The new financial measures look modest. The U.S. catches up with Europe in sanctioning Sberbank, the largest Russian bank, and both the U.S. and Europe have extended the ban on new debt and equity to include energy companies directly (not just their banks). It also may be meaningful that the term of allowed finance is reduced to 30 days (from 90 days). I continue to believe that comprehensive financial sector sanctions are where we are (and should be) headed, which would include exclusion from the payments system. That action would cause substantial and upfront pain on Russia, and have systemic implications for global markets, but we are a long way off from that. 5. Russia will help affected energy companies with limited financing from its sovereign wealth fund (subject to a cap on fund investments that is low relative to the investments affected) and the central bank will spend reserves defending the exchange rate. Still, it’s reasonable to expect further market disruption and ruble depreciation as these sanctions sink in. Analysts expect Russian oil production to slip as soon as 2015. 6. There remains inevitable momentum for additional sanctions, both to deal with evasion and because events on the ground will provide triggers for harsher action. Sanctions are “working” in the sense of imposing long-term costs on Russia, and these measures could add significantly to the cost. However, there continues to be a disconnect between a sanctions approach that aims to impose long-term costs and events on the ground that are moving at a much faster pace. At the same time, the Ukrainian IMF-backed program is veering off course and a widening financing gap is emerging that even debt restructuring may not fill. This creates a tension for policymakers that these measures do not resolve.
Europe
The Geopolitical Paradox: Dangerous World, Resilient Markets
Should we be worried by how well global markets are performing despite rising geopolitical volatility? I think so. In my September monthly, I look at the main arguments explaining the disconnect, and argue Europe is the region we should be most worried about a disruptive correction. Here are a few excerpts. • Far Away and Uncorrelated. Much of the market commentary has stressed that the risks that most worry political analysts—for example Russia, ISIL and Syria, Syria, an Ebola pandemic—are not necessarily central to global growth and market prospects. But small (in GDP terms)and far away does not mean inconsequential. As the debate over financial sanctions has shown, its Russia’s leverage and interconnectedness, rather than its global trade share, that makes comprehensive sanctions so powerful and potentially disruptive. • A Sea of Global Liquidity. There is little doubt that the highly accommodative monetary policies of the United States, eurozone, United Kingdom, and Japan have provided an important firewall against geopolitical risk. Looking ahead, global liquidity will remain ample, but with the U.S. and U.K. beginning to normalize, and the BOJ and ECB going in the other direction, the divergence of monetary policies creates conditions for increased market volatility. Foreign exchange markets in particular appear vulnerable, as history suggests these markets are often bellwethers of divergent monetary policies. • Confident Oil Markets. A stable and moderate global expansion that has limited demand, as well as the revolution in fracking and other technologies, has allowed Saudi Arabia to maintain substantial spare capacity, thereby limiting the potential for a supply disruption to roil markets in the near term (though the longer-term buffering effects on market prices from these developments can be overestimated). But it is hard to imagine that broad based turmoil in the middle east, and the possible rewriting of borders, can be achieved without a material disruption to supplies at some point. • Europe as the Weak Link. I see Europe as the channel through which political risk could reverberate in the global economy. The standoff with Russia, or a hard landing in China could significantly affect exports, particularly in Germany. Significantly, though, Europe also faces these challenges at a time of economic stress and limited resilience. Growth in the region has disappointed and leading indicators have tilted downward. Further, concern about deflation is beginning to weigh on sentiment and investment. The persistence of low inflation is symptomatic of deeper structural problems facing the eurozone, including an incomplete monetary union, deep-seated competitiveness problems in the periphery, and devastatingly high unemployment. Homegrown political risks also threaten to add to the turmoil, as rising discontent within Europe over the costs of austerity is undermining governing parties and fueling populism. The result is a monetary union with little capacity or resilience to defend against shocks. The ECB has responded to these risks with interest-rate cuts and asset purchases, and is expected to move to quantitative easing later this year or early next, but the move comes late, and is unlikely to do more than address the headwinds associated with the ongoing banking reform and continued fiscal austerity. Overall, a return to crisis is an increasing concern and political risks could be the trigger that we should be worried about.
  • International Organizations
    Financing Ukraine: Time for an Honest Assessment
    Russia’s invasion of Ukraine (“incursion” is far too polite a term) represents a major intensification of the conflict and should cross all red lines the West has established.  The logic of the earlier, incremental approach—put modest sanctions in place, and let the threat of worse create a chilling effect on investment and trade—has reached a dead end.  Whether President Putin seeks a stalemate within Ukraine or something more menacing, full sectoral sanctions (including, importantly, Russia’s access to payments systems) should now be put in place as a firm signal of western resolve.  The real cost-benefit to be done is not the costs on the West compared to Russia. Rather it is those relative costs contrasted against doing nothing and risking a situation that brings us closer to either armed conflict or acceptance of a new rule that states can redraw boundaries by force. German President Merkel has signaled that further sanctions are on the agenda for the September 30 EU leaders summit, and I expect the Obama Administration will move with them if not before. While military developments will dominate the headlines in coming days, Ukraine’s economic collapse should not be forgotten.  Another necessary piece of the West’s response is enhanced economic assistance. The IMF meets tomorrow to conclude their first review of their program for Ukraine.  They will, no doubt, forgive the slippages and missed commitments and conclude the review, which will clear the way for disbursal of at least $1.4 billion.  The Fund has also signaled today their willingness to move money forward from the back part of the program –“recalibrating” the program—in order to meet a widening financing gap.   This could include boosting the next disbursement, or combining the next two reviews, in order to get more money out the door to Ukraine in coming months. The bottom line is that the Fund must acknowledge a major revision to its outlook for Ukraine.  That makes sense, as the original program assumptions (see below) were wildly unrealistic at the time and are a dead letter now.  The deterioration of economic conditions since that time is significantly due to Russian aggression, but not entirely. The legacy of past economic mistakes and even modest austerity is contributing to a deep economic recession. I suspect that the worsening on the situation on the ground likely makes even these new assumptions a receding hope. A  realistic forecast would show a widening fiscal hole and unsustainable debt dynamics, even assuming Ukraine remains whole and free. That means that the real message from tomorrow’s IMF Board meeting will be that the program is badly underfinanced, and will need a substantial rethink in coming months.  That means either substantially more bilateral assistance from Europe or debt restructuring.  Markets still do not price this outcome.  Many market analysts note that there is only one sovereign-backed Eurobond maturing this year, a $1.6 billion Naftogaz bond due at end September, and that the IMF program already in principle provides the financing to pay this bond.  Why then make waves ahead of parliamentary elections scheduled for October 26 and given the uncertainty of Russia’s actions?  I have sympathy for this argument, but at the same time, the Fund’s internal rules require it to assert that the program is adequately financed, which means looking forward two years.  Further, there may well be strong political as well as economic benefits for the Ukrainian government of a more full-throated effort to bail in its creditors.  Honesty (and credibility) requires the kind of warnings that will make headlines in coming days.  It is hard to imagine that we do not begin to have the debate. Original IMF  Program (5/14) Current Market Estimates GDP Growth in 2014 -5.0% -8.0% to -10.0% Public Debt/GDP in 2018 61% 70%–80% Exchange Rate (per USD) in 2014 10.5 13.9 (current rate; 16 in black market) Fiscal deficit/GDP in 2014 -8.5% -10% to -11%
  • Budget, Debt, and Deficits
    Argentina Defaults: The Day After
    Argentina has defaulted. The long-running court drama that ran for over ten years and pitted Argentina against a small group of holdout creditors was decided decisively in favor of the holdouts in June, and Argentina subsequently refused to make payments as required by the courts. As a result, neither the holdouts nor the holders of restructured external debt will get paid, resulting in S&P placing the country in “selective default.” (Payment on the restructured bonds was due June 30, and the grace period for making those payments expired yesterday.) There is a great deal of back-and-forth on who is to blame, focusing mostly on the equity/ethical/moral implications of creditors (or vultures?) being rewarded for a litigating their contractual rights against a distressed sovereign that has carried out an internationally supported restructuring. That’s a big question, not answered here (though I do believe that Argentina’s problems are mostly of their own making, and this court case a convenient scapegoat).  Here are a few thoughts on what to look for in coming days. What comes next? Negotiations will continue, and there will continue to be talk of a possible deal that would end the default, including a plan where local banks buy the debt and sell it to the government. I’m deeply skeptical. Over the last 10 years, Argentina essentially has not budged from the position that holdouts would get no better deal than those that restructured. As the court cases went against them, that offer became less and less attractive to the creditors, the courts became more resistant to stays and other rulings to protect Argentina, and the gap between the parties became so vast that it is hard to imagine any side caving now. Indeed, the political cost within Argentina of the government now paying off the holdouts seems extraordinarily high, suggesting that we may need a new government before a negotiated solution is possible. Credit Default Swaps (CDS) will be triggered. In the Greek restructuring, there was a lot of concern that triggering CDS would have systemic effects. It didn’t. The relevant committee (ISDA) likely will judge this to be a credit event, and those who sold insurance through credit default swaps will pay out. Because some creditors may have significant CDS protection, triggering makes it easier to know who is a true creditor of the country and can align interests in a negotiation. Watch local markets. What is the cost of default for Argentina? This is a local market story--today’s selloff in global equity markets has less to do with Argentina and more to do with Russian sanctions and U.S. monetary policy concerns. Argentina has long been excluded from international markets, and though there was hope that they would re-access those markets, on the day after default little has changed. Local debt is still being paid. The economy is still a mess. So, from that perspective, the position of the country hasn’t changed much. Yet, many expect local market turmoil, including exchange rate pressures and higher interest rates, which could be a tough economic hit. Any of a number of triggers can start a run/crisis, and if one it happens the government has limited resources to defend against it. A domestic crisis could put pressure on all parties—Argentina, its creditors, and the courts—to compromise. Look for innovative legal approaches. I’m convinced that the legal situation will remain murky for some time, given the complexity and diversity of debt contracts, and the differing incentives to accelerate/litigate. But we should take the time to explore creative approaches that may be possible post default. My favorite is Anna Gelpern’s, who notes that once all debt is accelerated the court’s remedy allows for interest payments only to all creditors. I have no idea whether it would work, but watch this space.