Blogs

Macro and Markets

Kahn analyzes economic policies for an integrated world.

Latest Post

Headquarters of Sberbank, one of the Russian institutions under U.S. sanctions
Headquarters of Sberbank, one of the Russian institutions under U.S. sanctions REUTERS/Sergei Karpukhin

Have Sanctions Become the Swiss Army Knife of U.S. Foreign Policy?

The Congress takes an important, positive step to reinforce Russian sanctions, but are we at risk of overusing the sanctions tool? Read More

Europe
Greece: Banking on Controls
It is time for banking controls in Greece. Delay at this point will only compound the chaos. Consider the following. Thursday’s meeting of Euro-area finance ministers made no progress toward a deal. That was not surprising. What was more noticeable was the discord that followed. IMF Managing Director Christine Lagarde summed it up: for a Greek deal to happen, there will have to be “adults in the room”. There will now be an emergency leader’s summit on Monday, but absent a major U-turn by the Greek government, that meeting is likely to turn to a discussion of “plan b.” Against this backdrop, there has been a rapid acceleration in outflows from the banking system, reportedly in excess of €2bn in the first three days of week. Deposit flight likely will intensify tomorrow and Monday. The ECB will hold an emergency phone call this morning to decide whether to expand emergency assistance (ELA) to the Greek banking system from its current limit of €81 billion. To keep the banks open, the ECB will need to provide a significant injection of liquidity. They should not do it. Greek banks are clearly insolvent. The crisis has caused a spike in non-performing loans, the economy is deteriorating rapidly, and with the Greek government on the verge of default to the IMF, the ECB can no longer pretend that the Greek government bonds that the banks have provided as collateral for past loans are adequate protection against loss. (Arrears to the IMF do not force other creditors’ claims into default, but the political statement of non-cooperation would be powerful unless serious negotiations are underway.) Further, ready access to central bank liquidity has disabled an important source of market discipline on the government, throws good money after bad, and creditor frustration with the continuing demands for financing make the politics of a deal all the more challenging. The Greek government is likely to resist imposing banking controls, but absent an agreement with creditors controls on deposit withdrawals and cross-border transfers look unavoidable once ECB liquidity support has been curtailed. Controls will buy some time for the government, but how much is unclear. The immediate challenge is fiscal and domestic. The government reported a sharp fall in fiscal revenue last month, reflecting a declining economy and substantial tax non-compliance. In response, it has slashed spending and delayed payments to suppliers and contractors. But large-scale arrears are causing significant payments difficulties in the broader economy, and are not sustainable for long when banks can’t lend. For this reason, I am skeptical that the government can sustain deficit spending for long through creation of IOUs, a informal secondary currency within Greece. How the government responds to these fiscal challenges will go a long way to determining whether controls are a way station to Grexit or, as elsewhere (e.g., Cyprus), breathing space to restructure and adjust within the currency union. My colleague Sebastian Mallaby has an excellent discussion of the perils for Greece of heading down this path, and he makes a convincing case that Grexit is not an easy option. The converse is also true. The international community has coalesced around the policies needed to put Greece on a sustainable path within the Eurozone. That includes additional debt relief and perhaps as much as 2 percentage points of GDP in new measures this year alone—including to pensions, wages, and taxes—measures that the Greek government has firmly rejected and that would be a major economic and political challenge to pass and implement. If Greece were to accept the deal, Europe would need to provide additional debt relief to make the numbers add up, a point recently emphasized by the IMF. Tough decisions are called for on both sides, and the prospect for bridging this gap is looking increasingly remote. While the temptation thus exists to buy time by extending the current program, trading cash for partial reforms, and putting off negotiations on a third bailout until the fall, it is a “bridge to nowhere” if it doesn’t put Greece on a credible path back to sustainable growth.            
Europe
Greece’s Bridge to Nowhere
Negotiations continue today between Greece and its creditors, with reports that the government has presented a revised proposal that offers minor concessions in an effort to break the deadlock. A deal is needed in the next week if a package of assistance is to be put in place before end-month payments of $1.7 billion are due to the IMF. While this is not a hard deadline—a short-term default to the IMF need not sink the Greek economy—the government is out of cash and it is hard to imagine how they make critical domestic payments without an injection of cash from creditors. At times like this, the focus is always on getting a deal done, but this negotiation, even if successful, is likely to defer hard choices for a few months in the hope that Greek domestic politics will change to allow a third bail-out program. The two sides are far apart, both in terms of the policies that need to be taken in the short term and the longer term vision for restoring growth. It is hard not to conclude this is a bridge to nowhere.  A few points. The two sides are farther apart than the headline numbers suggest. The revised Greek proposal offers a primary surplus of 0.75 percent this year, 1.75 percent in 2016 and 2.75 percent in 2017, compared to the creditor proposal of one, two and three percent, respectively. Seemingly small amounts and one could wrongly conclude the sides are close, but these numbers mask major differences in policy. With current policies, Greece will run a primary deficit this year of around 2/3 of a percent of GDP, and if the government moves ahead with proposed changes to labor and pension laws, the deficit could be substantially larger. Partly this deficit reflects the fall in activity, partly it reflects policy measures from the new government. Thus, even to hit the Greek targets require around 1½ percent of GDP in new measures this year, and substantial additional reforms in subsequent years. This is a lot to ask of a government built on a fragile coalition of interests and elected to do the opposite. Elections have consequences. The core policies in any deal are well known. Creditors have outlined a set of proposals that will need to form the basis for any deal. They reportedly include: (i) an increase in the VAT, currently one of the lowest in the EU, to raise collections by 1 percent of GDP; (ii) public sector wage cuts of 1 percent annually starting next year; (iii) pension cuts of around 1 percent of GDP by 2017 to put the pension system on a fully-paid basis; (iv) a redesigned social safety net system saving ½ percent of GDP per year; and (v) a labor consultation process that would put the brakes on the government’s efforts to roll back previous labor market reforms. There are also privatization proposals, but the program shouldn’t hinge on that element given the inherent uncertainty and lags involved. Creditors have signaled a willingness to negotiate the numbers, but it is hard to imagine a deal that doesn’t include these elements. The pension issue appears the most divisive, though creditors should be willing to accept a continuing pension deficit if the amounts are made up elsewhere. While pro-growth in the longer-term, these policies are a near-term drag on activity at a difficult time. To the frustration of Greece’s creditors, the government has failed on multiple occasions to come up with a coherent or well-developed set of proposals to achieve these savings. The revised Greek proposal reportedly focuses on the headline numbers and comprehensive debt relief, instead of the policies. I have long been supportive of substantial debt relief for Greece (and other overly indebted periphery countries), but I also believe that the creditor’s proposals are a reasonable price to ask in return. That is the grand bargain that should be the goal. But while both sides can be criticized, it is hard not to conclude that the government knows what policies are needed to clinch a deal, but that they are simply unwilling or unable at this point to agree to such policies. Perhaps there is a “Hastert rule” in play in Greece, and the government cannot politically go ahead with a program that does not command a majority of Syriza parliamentarians (opposition parties have signaled their willingness to support a deal). The bottom line here is that while the headline differences are small, the policy and political gulf is vast. The G7 closes ranks. At this weekend’s G7 meeting, there was a strong consensus that Greece needed to make tough and significant decisions to get a deal done.  The United States had in recent weeks been seen to be pressing European leaders to compromise, but President Obama’s statement showed little space between him and the other members of the G7:  "What it’s going to require is Greece being serious about making some important reforms not only to satisfy creditors, but, more importantly, to create a platform whereby the Greek economy can start growing again and prosper.  And so the Greeks are going to have to follow through and make some tough political choices that will be good for the long term." Domestic payments are still the trip wire. Even if most or all external debt payments were deferred or forgiven, Greece would still need additional resources in the near term while negotiations on a longer term program proceed. A bank run adds to the needs. The government proposes to meet the need through additional treasury bill issuance, which in the end would be financed by the ECB’s Emergency Liquidity Assistance (ELA). ELA exposure to Greece now stands at around €80 billion, and it is understandable that the ECB is wary of being the lender of first resort for an open-ended transitional period. But without this support, growing domestic arrears and missed payments will have a damaging effect on an already slowing economy and put further political pressure on the government. Banking controls inevitably would follow. In the end, non-payment to the IMF need not cause huge dislocations for the Greek economy. Not paying pensions or government wages in full would. The inflation tax is becoming more attractive. One often-cited advantage from leaving the eurozone is the growth boost that could come from the resultant depreciation, but that presumes that Greece could develop a vibrant non-tourist export sector with a more competitive exchange rate. That is hard to imagine being done easily given current policies. Perhaps a more powerful near-term argument for exit is simply that it relieves fiscal pressure by allowing the government to print money. The inflation tax that results is hugely distortive, but not necessarily more so than the current situation of widespread and growing domestic arrears. In the end, whether there is a deal or not is a political decision with substantial consequence for Greece and also for Europe. But beyond handicapping the deal, it is important to have a path for Greece that restores growth, and it’s hard to see how we are closer to that outcome now than before the most recent crisis.
Europe
Greece—a Destabilizing Financial Squeeze
Technical talks between Greece and the Troika concluded today without a deal, another setback for Greece as domestic financial stress mounts.  Robin Brooks at Goldman-Sachs makes the important point—financial conditions have tightened sharply, and will have adverse and destabilizing effects on growth regardless of whether there is a deal next week between Greece and its European creditors on a reform package.  Household deposits in Greece (red line in the left chart) and deposits in non-financial corporations (right chart) have fallen sharply, causing a destructive tightening in financial conditions at a time when banks are already in trouble and constricting credit. (Anecdotal evidence suggests this trend is continuing, with additional outflows from Greek banks in March.) At the same time, a severe squeeze on fiscal resources is forcing the government to make tough decisions about who to pay and who not to pay—which I have called “the politics of arrears”. Greece: Financial conditions Source: Goldman Sachs The experience with emerging markets highlights the high political and economic costs of a financial and fiscal squeeze.  In the run-up to Russia’s 1998 crisis, wage and interfirm arrears paralleled a weakening of budget discipline and were reflective of what the IMF came to call a “culture of non-payment” that undermined support for continued adjustment and was an impediment to recovery. In Argentina, after the introduction of banking sector controls in December 2001, financial conditions tightened sharply and arrears at the federal and local level mounted quickly. Paper IOUs issued by governments traded at deep discounts, and eventually most liabilities of the government and private sector were written down at preferred rates as part of an “asymmetric repesofication” by the government. A third example comes more recently from Venezuela, where the moral and political implications of continuing to pay external debt at a time when the government is running comprehensive domestic arrears and rationing foreign currency has generated a firestorm of debate. Weak fundamentals create the conditions for crisis, but payments problems determine the end game. Robin argues that the risk of Grexit is rising, and I agree; it will become increasingly hard for the government to sustain support for its program and for continued participation in the eurozone as tight financial conditions cause a renewed recession.  Recent polls show Greek support for euro membership, but that could change quickly if stress intensifies. So while the long-term sustainability of Greece in the eurozone depends on fundamentals (e.g., a competitive, flexible economy and competitive exchange rate), the decisions the government makes in coming days domestically on payments and banking controls may have more to do with the outcome of the crisis than negotiations with European finance ministers.
  • Europe
    Greece and the Politics of Arrears
    Greece is running out of money. Greek Prime Minister Alexis Tsipras’s meeting this week with German Chancellor Angela Merkel has taken some of the toxicity out of the conversation for now, but cannot mask Greece’s current collision course with its creditors. Committed to a platform on which it was elected but that it cannot pay for, and with additional EU/ECB financing conditioned on reform, the Greek government is likely to run out of money in April (if not before). If past emerging market crises are any guide, the decisions that it will then confront about who to pay and who not to—the politics of arrears—will present a critical challenge to the government and likely define the future path of the crisis. Most analysts continue to argue that a deal that allows Greece to muddle through and avoid an exit from the eurozone (“Grexit”) is the most likely outcome. This argument is usually based on the assessment that there is a deal to be had, that Prime Minister Tsipras is a realistic leader that can over time navigate his coalition to a course that balances democratic accountability and a return to growth with the reforms needed to continue to receive assistance, and that both sides have too much to lose from a messy exit. All this may be true, but the political timeline over which this scenario plays out is measured in months, while the economic timeline is measured in days. The Greek government is now moving to prepare a more detailed set of reforms (including fiscal reform, privatization, social security and labor measures), based on the February 20 Eurogroup agreement, in hope of securing the approval in coming days from eurozone finance ministers. Any agreement reached will require approval by the Greek and foreign parliaments. Interim meetings can at best provide momentum to negotiations that justify short-term financing—most likely in small amounts and conditional on progress—while these negotiations proceed. That means that Greece will soon, perhaps as early as next week, begin to run arrears. How did we get here? Tax revenue collapsed in the run up to the election, and has contracted further in the uncertainty that has followed. Further, in recent weeks, the parliament has approved a number of anti-poverty measures and a payment plan for tax debtors, generating domestic support but taking policy further away from the previously approved program. It is unclear whether more controversial, but necessary reforms could win approval. As a result, even the reduced government primary surplus of 1.5 percent of GDP looks out of reach on current policies. This is not to criticize the government for seeking to keep its election promises, but rather to stress the large and growing gulf between its plans and what European creditors are willing to support. Unsurprisingly, bank deposits have begun to flow out of the system in the past week (reportedly as much as 350–400 million euros on some days), exacerbating liquidity problems. By some reports, Greece needs about 2 billion euros to meet its remaining obligations for March and more for April when it faces material debt payments, including to the IMF. Reports are that it will be able to cover the March pension and wage payments from its deposits and it can tap the reserves of pension funds, state bodies and utilities, but the outlook from then onward is unclear. Greek officials are reportedly considering the use of IOUs for the payment of salaries and pensions, and less politically sensitive payments to suppliers are also likely to lag. In his letter to Chancellor Merkel last week, Prime Minister Tsipras signaled that the government might not have sufficient resources for April and would not make debt payments at the expense of social stability. What comes next? The Greek government would like to tap EU bailout funds, but acknowledges that will take time. In the interim, they are looking for the ECB to provide financing—primarily though the Bank of Greece’s emergency liquidity assistance (ELA) mechanism which now stands around 70 billion—to illiquid Greek banks, which in turn can buy government paper. There should be no mistake that to do so would be pure fiscal financing. Consequently, it is not surprising that the ECB has opposed lifting the 3.5 billion euro cap on the amount of T-bills it will accept as collateral in exchange for central bank loans. What we have seen in emerging market crises in the past is that the running of arrears puts extraordinary pressure on a government, and this new Greek government is unlikely to be an exception. The decision to pay some and not others involves allocative choices that will be new terrain for the government. Suppliers and other providers of government services are likely to see arrears, differing across different sectors depending on the power of the relevant ministries and the revealed priorities of the government. IOUs might circulate but likely would trade at a deep discount given poor liquidity conditions.  Capital controls may be needed to stem flight, putting further strain on the economy. Fissures within the governing coalition could open up. This process is unlikely to be structured and orderly. In the end, should Greece survive the politics of arrears, they will still need a competitive economy and sustainable fiscal finances, and it is hard to see how the government’s current program gets them there. Sustainability can be achieved through Grexit (and the subsequent devaluation and debt restructuring), or it can be done though a rewriting of contracts to get relative prices right and reduce liabilities (“internal devaluation”) followed by an easing of controls. Either is possible, though the experience of Iceland and Cyprus remind us of the difficulty of getting rid of capital controls once they are in place. Either can produce a sustainable post-crisis Greece. That will be a big decision down the road, but for now Greece’s future is likely to be decided by the decisions made in coming weeks on who gets paid.  
  • Budget, Debt, and Deficits
    Ukraine’s IMF Program Sets Stage for Debt Restructuring
    The IMF yesterday approved a four-year, $17.5 billion arrangement for Ukraine, their contribution to a $40 billion financing gap that they have identified over that period. A further $15 billion is to come from a restructuring of private debt, with formal negotiations expected to begin soon. The rest is expected to come from governments and other multilateral agencies. An ambitious array of reforms—including to fiscal and energy policy, bank reform, and strengthening the rule of law—are laid out, signaling a dramatic break from past governments. These measures are expected to set the stage for recovery: output falls 5 ½ percent this year before 2 percent growth returns in 2016, inflation will average 27 percent this year and then decline, while the current account deficit falls to 1 ½ percent and the currency stabilizes around current levels. Public sector debt will peak at 94 percent of GDP in 2015 as the program takes hold. All this depends on an end to the current hostilities, which as the IMF notes remains a considerable risk to the program. These numbers have little meaning. The odds of this program surviving intact for four years, or even through the end of 2015, are not much higher than for the original 2014 program which was junked yesterday. Private forecasters predict a deeper recession (as much as a 10 percent decline this year and a further fall next year). Consider the IMF’s program a vision for where it would like to see Ukraine go, and focus on the cash flows that Ukraine will get in 2015 and the near term policy reforms they will need to implement to receive the money (many of which were passed recently by the parliament). From that perspective, yesterday’s deal provides critical near-term financial support, but is not enough to grow the economy while the war continues. The judgment that the program will not last is not a rejection of the effort. The Fund deserves a great deal of credit for getting the program to the finish line in extraordinarily difficult conditions, and the $5 billion first disbursement from the Fund provides critical cash to the budget ($2.7 billion, with the remainder going to bolster international reserves), and should catalyze other official money. Ukraine can expect an additional $5 billion of IMF money in three equal tranches if the program stays on track through 2015, as well as $6.3 billion in other official funding. IMF Board approval triggers the start of negotiations with Ukraine’s private creditors on a debt restructuring. The IMF has set a target of $15 billion for the operation in cash flow relief over the four years. There are a lot of ways to get to that number, and the Fund is purposely vague on what it is looking for. The public debate has focused on whether the deal will be a “reprofiling” (a moderate extension of maturities with little or no cut in interest rates, a sort of stand-still to keep creditors engaged until uncertainty is resolved) or a deep restructuring. The outcome is likely to be somewhere in between, with substantial interest rate cuts (at least for the first few years) required to meet the Fund’s target. That means substantial uncertainty will persist about whether further debt reduction will be needed, a problem for a program that optimistically assumes a return to markets by Ukraine in the next three years. Publicly, the negotiations will be left to Ukraine, its financial advisors, and its private creditors. But don’t be surprised to see that the IMF and the major creditor governments call the shots in these negotiations, and the Fund’s next disbursement scheduled for June is dependent on the expected conclusion of a successful debt operation with high participation. The report is more realistic in a number of respects than the program it replaced. I have been quite critical of the Fund for its rosy economic and political assumptions, and its view that the program had a “high probability” of success, all of which contributed to the underfunding of Ukraine over the past year. Such optimism was driven more by the Fund’s internal rules for lending than a clear-eyed assessment of the situation. Instead, this time the Fund acknowledges “exceptional risks” and IMF Managing Director Christine Lagarde simply suggests that “with continued firm implementation, there is a reasonably strong prospect of success.” Perhaps we have a new standard for Fund programs in the future.