Blogs

Energy, Security, and Climate

CFR experts examine the science and foreign policy surrounding climate change, energy, and nuclear security.

Latest Post

REUTERS/Amit Dave
REUTERS/Amit Dave

Why We Still Need Innovation in Successful Clean Energy Technologies

Today is my last day at CFR. I’m joining ReNew Power, India’s largest renewable energy firm, as their CTO. I’m excited for a new adventure but sad to leave the Council, which has given me support and autonomy to study the innovations needed for global decarbonization. Read More

Fossil Fuels
A Must Read New Book on Oil, Finance, and Economic History
In 1863, with the first American oil boom “at full tilt”, Andrew Carnegie had an epiphany: the world would soon run out of oil. He and a partner “decided to dig an enormous hole, capable of holding 100,000 barrels of oil”, where they would stockpile crude “until the worldwide oil shortage had struck”. When that happened, they’d be rich – to be precise, they’d be millionaires. As Blake Clayton recalls in his awesome new book Market Madness: A Century of Oil Panics, Crises, and Crashes, they then waited. “And waited. But the long-awaited shortage never came. The only thing that did arrive was evaporation, which kept skimming more and more oil off the top of the lake.” Carnegie, writing fifty-seven years later, “noted wryly that the shortage… still had ‘not arrived’”. I’m not an impartial observer – Blake did much of the work on this book while he was a fellow with my program at the Council on Foreign Relations, where he’s still an adjunct – but don’t let that lead you to discount my enthusiasm. This is a fascinating book: it’s simultaneously an entertaining story of four peak oil scares (and how they end) stretching back over a hundred years; an analytically serious book about behavioral finance that helps explain how markets can often be incredibly wrong; and a careful look at how policy makers manage – and mismanage – energy strategy in the face of uncertainty and fear. In any case, don’t just take my word for it. Dan Yergin calls the book “fascinating and lively”. Greg Sharenow of PIMCO calls it “a landmark study that is a must read for investors and policymakers alike”. And Charley Ebinger predicts that it “will rank with Daniel Yergin’s The Prize as an icon in the field”. Don’t bet against that. You can buy the book here. And, in a year or so, you’ll probably want to buy the paperback too – its epilogue about the latest oil crash is bound to be a must-read.
Fossil Fuels
Politics and Policy Still Critically Shape Oil Markets and Prices
Where will oil prices ultimately shake out? I argue in an FT op-ed today that political dynamics sparked by falling prices will be as important as purely economic forces in determining the answer: “The assumption that politics, whether Saudi manipulation or collusion in the OPEC oil producers’ cartel, would keep prices eternally above $100 a barrel was proved wrong [by the oil price crash]. Now people are flipping to an opposite view, where market forces are king and politics no longer matters. Instead of reading the tea leaves in Riyadh and Vienna, they are focusing narrowly on how commodities and capital markets will adjust to low prices — which in isolation is just as wrong and just as dangerous.” The piece works through potential supply-side policy shifts by both low- and high-costs producers and possible demand-side changes too. Each is worth an extensive analysis in its own right, and none have been getting serious treatment by analysts so far. This is a largely understandable short-term reflex – it is right to believe that markets, not energy policy, are now central to shaping oil prices in the short-run. But it is the wrong way to look at long-run responses to lower oil prices. The piece doesn’t talk about “geopolitics” in the traditional market-analyst sense –upheaval in Nigeria or Venezuela, macroeconomic policy in Europe, and such. There’s no debate that such things will always influence prices. What’s essential to remember is that, OPEC or no OPEC, policies that might shift directly in response to lower oil prices still matter. You can read the whole piece here.
Fossil Fuels
The Oil Lesson of 1986 is Wrong
When I was on the road promoting The Power Surge in 2013, I regularly said two things: First, oil prices could easily plunge for a year or two, though it was far from certain that that would happen. Second, we would not see a repeat of 1986, when the hangover from a price crash lasted for well over a decade before high prices finally returned. As oil prices have fallen, it’s been pleasantly surprising not to see people trot out the 1986 episode as evidence that we might be in for a decade or more of low oil prices once again. Earlier this week, though, a Bloomberg writer decided to buck the trend with “Oil Collapse of 1986 Shows Rebound Could Be Years Away”. The "Chart of the Day" from that article, reprinted here, pretty much tells the story. But 2014 isn’t 1986. Then, massive investment in oil production following the twin oil crises of the 1970s led to a buildup of long-lived oil production capacity. With money spent, that production capacity cost very little to operate. Prices needed to stay low for several years to throttle not only new investment but also production back. Non-OPEC oil production fell every year between 1988 and 1993. Weak demand also played an important role. While consumption originally rose after 1986 in response to lower prices, between 1989 and 1993, world oil consumption rose by a mere 1.5 million barrels a day, dragged down by the collapse of the Soviet Union and economic weakness more broadly. The biggest difference today is the supply picture. In 1986, the world faced an overhang of conventional oil production capacity. Today, it is buffeted by a surge in tight oil production. The difference is stark. Once investment in tight oil stops, output from existing wells drops sharply, which is very different from what happens with conventional wells. This can, in principle, balance the market much more quickly than was possible in the 1980s. Of course investment in U.S. production hasn’t come to a halt. That’s why most analysts still expect supply growth this year. But this is a fundamentally different situation from the mid-1980s. If oil prices stay low for as long as they did after 1986, it will be because tight oil production turns out to be massively scalable at remarkably low prices while remaining profitable, not because sunk investment costs have created oil producing zombies that continue pumping at almost any price. (It could also happen if the world rapidly accelerated the deployment of low-cost alternatives and efficiency.) The aftermath of 1986 was almost inevitable at the time given the investment that had already happened. (This brackets the far-from-inevitable decisions by Saudi Arabia and others to boost their own production after 1986.) What happens over the next decade in oil markets still remains very much to be determined.
  • Fossil Fuels
    One More Reason to Raise the Gas Tax Now
    Three months ago gas taxes were untouchable. Now, with oil prices down, they’re having a moment. Public voices from Larry Summers to Charles Krauthammer are calling for hikes. (Summers argues for a carbon tax; Krauthammer says the tax should be raised “a lot”.) More important, serious lawmakers from both sides of the aisle have gotten in on the game. The general thrust of the arguments on offer is that with oil prices falling, it’s now possible to raise the gas tax and still leave consumers better off than they were half a year ago. That right, but I think there’s an even stronger argument to be made. The standard argument is basically a political case about what voters will tolerate. (The theory is that they’ll tolerate a higher gas tax if they’re still better off than before.) It’s then paired with preexisting economic logic (a higher gasoline tax made economic sense when oil prices were higher too). This is essentially the pattern I flagged in a Financial Times column in November, when I argued that falling oil prices were creating an opportunity for leaders in developing countries to curb gasoline and diesel subsidies. But there is an economic case that’s peculiar to the current situation to be made too. Whenever you impose a new and unanticipated tax, some part of the existing capital stock becomes less valuable than it was before. (Some other part typically becomes more valuable, but if market participants were rational before, this downside should be smaller than the upside.) Adding, say, fifty cents to a gallon of gasoline makes pre-existing gas guzzlers, homes in the suburbs, and oil-based home heating systems worth less than before. Normally, that would reduce the net benefits of any new gasoline tax, particularly one phased in quickly. Conversely, when oil prices fall, fuel efficient cars, homes in city-centers, and public transit investments all drop in value. This can lead to economic waste: underused automobiles, unrented homes, empty subways. A particularly glaring example came on Wednesday when President Obama visited a Ford plant that makes fuel-efficient vehicles: because of the drop in oil prices, that plant was closed, wasting both the factory and the skills of the workers that it would have employed. In this world, a newly higher gasoline tax would actually avoid economic waste rather than creating it. Ford and others that invested money on the expectation that oil prices would remain relatively high (and, if options prices on oil futures as recently as six months ago are any indication, that means most businesses) would see their investments hold more value. The same goes for drivers who, facing higher oil prices, already spent their money on ever-more-fuel-efficient cars. (They’d still pay more at the pump, but the resale value of their cars would rise.) One can go down the list of oil-sensitive consumers and find more examples like this. Similar logic underpinned proposals from Robert Lawrence and from Jason Bordoff and Gilbert Metcalf several years ago for a variable gas tax that smoothed consumer prices (up when oil prices fell; down when they rose): it would allow consumers to better prepare for the future and would thus avoid economic waste. No one is talking about a variable tax now, but by hiking gas taxes while oil prices have fallen, lawmakers would be manually mimicking the mechanisms that these analysts proposed be made automatic. To be certain, there would still be losers as well as winners from raising the gasoline tax now. But almost everyone would come out ahead compared to where they were a year ago, and many would be even better off than they were with low gas prices but without the gas tax. Not everyone fits in one of those two categories – in particular, there is nothing here that’s good for oil companies, who would face less demand for their product over time. (Though combined oil and gas companies could make money on the other side from buildings that switch from oil to gas heating.) But that was always the case with any gasoline tax, and less important than many other policy decisions to the oil companies’ bottom lines. It has always made economic sense to make consumers pay for the full costs of the gasoline they use. There have also always been legitimate worries about the impact of higher gas taxes on vulnerable consumers, but those can be addressed by using the proceeds of a tax effectively. The fall in oil prices just adds to the reasons for getting U.S. energy prices right.
  • Fossil Fuels
    What Low Oil Prices Mean for the Keystone XL Pipeline
    The 114th Congress is in session and the Keystone XL pipeline is at the top of its docket. Senate Republicans have vowed to push the pipeline through and President Obama has threatened to veto any bill that does that. After five years of battle, this is mostly more of the same. But one thing about the world has changed radically since the Keystone XL pipeline became a top tier issue: oil prices have plunged. So what do lower oil prices mean for the costs and benefits of the Keystone XL pipeline? Expert discussion has been focused on the State Department Environmental Impact Statement (SEIS). This is more relevant to political handicapping than to actual cost-benefit analysis, but it’s still worth digging into. The SEIS concluded that the pipeline would probably have no “substantial impact” on greenhouse gas emissions. This seemed to line up with President Obama’s statement that he would only approve the pipeline if it did not “significantly exacerbate” climate change. But the SEIS claimed that there was one exception: if oil prices were between $65 and $75, the Keystone XL pipeline could make a significant difference, tipping the economics of Canadian oil production from red to black and thus increasing emissions. Hence the political hook. Indeed as oil prices fell below $75 late last year, I began getting calls from reporters asking if this was a game changer for Keystone. Once oil dropped below $65, the calls stopped. The $65-$75 range was never particularly compelling in the first place. No matter what the prevailing price of oil, if you reduce the cost of transporting it, you will improve project economics, and, at the margin, you should expect oil companies to produce more. How much more is impossible to confidently predict. Among other things, the breakeven price for Canadian oil will likely move with the oil price and with transport costs: if nudging transport costs a little when oil costs $70 a barrel really does threaten to shut in a large amount of Canadian oil, there’s a good chance that the Alberta government will try to blunt the impact through changes in tax and royalty treatment. On top of all that, of course, is the fact that oil is no longer trading between $65 and $75, and no one knows when it next will. It’s much more interesting to ask how lower oil prices affect the costs and benefits of approving the pipeline. As a starting point, it’s important to stipulate that no one really knows where the long-run oil price will settle. And it’s the long-run price, not the current one, which matters when you’re talking about the consequences of a pipeline that has the potential to operate for decades. So let’s focus on what “lower” oil prices mean for Keystone XL rather than what any particular prices does. Lower oil prices reduce both the costs and the benefits of approving the Keystone XL pipeline by reducing the odds that it will ever be fully used. There’s an outside chance that, if prices are sustained at an extremely low level, the Keystone XL pipeline won’t get built. That scenario isn’t likely – among other things, if Canadian production doesn’t grow, the odds of sustained low prices decline substantially – but it’s not zero. Lower prices also raise the odds that the pipeline will be built but not fully utilized. In that case, you still get the up-front construction stimulus, but you get less benefit from greater oil production, and less climate damage from the same. You also have a waste of economic resources. The more likely scenario, though, is that the Keystone XL pipeline gets built and used. In that case, lower oil prices reduce its economic benefits without any clear impact on its climate costs. If you assume a constant elasticity of oil demand, then a given addition to world oil production should push down prices by the same percentage, regardless of what the starting point is. Imagine you think that the Keystone pipeline would boost net world oil production by 100,000 barrels of oil a day and you believe that would cut world oil prices by 0.3 percent. If prevailing oil prices start at $100, you’re cutting them by 30 cents; if they start at $50, you’re reducing them by only 15 cents. In both cases the marginal reduction in oil prices saves Americans money through reduced import costs and reduced absolute price volatility. (There is one countervailing force – at lower oil prices, U.S. imports are higher, and therefore a given reduction in oil prices yields more economic benefit – but this shouldn’t fully offset the main economic effect.) The upshot is that, in the lower oil price world, any savings from Keystone XL are reduced. What about the climate impact? For a given net impact of Keystone XL on world oil production, the climate damages should be unchanged – the impact is a fixed function of how much extra oil is produced in Canada and how much additional oil is consumed worldwide. So whatever you think the excess of benefits over costs is for Keystone at $100 a barrel oil (and many people, of course, think that “excess” is negative), you ought to think that it’s smaller when prevailing oil prices are reduced. Keystone XL, like any oil production project, is less compelling when prices are lower. What about the absolute impact on both economics and climate? This is much more difficult to pin down. The absolute impact of Keystone XL on both depends on how other producers respond in the long run to any additional production that it enables – that’s what determines the net impact on world production and consumption. How that changes depending on the prevailing oil price is unclear. Nailing that down would require knowledge of global oil supply economics, as well as oil producer politics, that no one confidently has. What hasn’t changed is that both the climate damages and the economic benefits from Keystone XL are small in the grand schemes of climate change and the U.S. and global economies. A Keystone XL decision will have much larger consequences for U.S. politics, U.S.-Canada relations, and perhaps the broader rules-based global trading system than it will for climate change or the economy – and that’s where serious decision-makers ought to mostly focus. Lower oil prices haven’t changed any of that.